from Part II - The Combinatorial Clock Auction Designs
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 26 October 2017
Introduction
The design of auction protocols and systems has received considerable academic attention in the recent years and found application in industrial procurement, logistics, and in public tenders (Airiau and Sen, 2003; Bellantuono et al., 2013). Spectrum auction design is one of the most challenging and visible applications. It is often seen as a pivotal example for the design of multi-object markets and successful auction designs are likely role-models for other markets in areas such as procurement and logistics.
Efficiency, revenue, and strategic simplicity for bidders are typical design goals that a regulator has in mind. In theory, theVickrey-Clarke-Groves (VCG) auction is the only strategy-proof and efficient auction but for practical reasons, it has rarely been used so far (Rothkopf, 2007). Several other auction formats have been designed and used for selling spectrum. The most prominent example is the Simultaneous Multi-Round Auction (SMRA) which has been used since the mid-90s to sell spectrum licenses world-wide. The more recent Combinatorial Clock Auction (CCA) is a two-phase auction format with an initial ascending clock auction and a sealed-bid supplementary bid phase afterward. It has lately been used to sell spectrum in countries such as Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Ireland, the Netherlands, Slovenia, and the UK.
The CCA draws on a number of elegant ideas inspired by economic theory. A revealed preference activity rule should provide incentives for bidders to bid straightforward or consistent, i.e., to bid truthfully on one of the payoff-maximizing packages in each round of the clock phase. If bidders fail to maximize utility and bid on a package with a less than optimal payoff, we will also refer to this as inconsistent bidding behavior, i.e., bids which are not consistent with the assumption of utility maximization. A second-price rule should set incentives to bid all valuations truthfully in the second sealed-bid phase. It can be shown that if bidders respond to these incentives in both phases of the CCA, then the outcome is efficient and in the core (Ausubel et al., 2006). However, bidders might not have incentives to bid truthful in both phases, and this can lead to inefficiencies.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.