Hostname: page-component-54dcc4c588-2ptsp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-09-11T23:13:52.192Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Autocrats and Their Business Allies: The Informal Politics of Defection and Co-optation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 August 2025

Semuhi Sinanoglu*
Affiliation:
German Institute of Development and Sustainability, Bonn, Germany
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Why do business allies (not) defect from authoritarian regimes? An emerging scholarship shows that connected businesses face high political risk, and the autocrat can financially pressure business allies during economic crises. And yet, despite their disruptive power, the business elite rarely switch to opposition. I argue that this unexpected loyalty does not always stem from credible power-sharing. The more material quid pro quo the business elite engage in with the dictator, the less they can credibly threaten the dictator with defection. I present a bargaining game between the dictatorship and its business allies and test it using a country-year-level dataset of 76 countries for 1992–2019. The results indicate that higher degrees of patrimonial co-optation lower the risk of business opposition. This effect is partly mediated through the government’s control over the media landscape. These findings suggest that even informal, non-institutional tools of co-optation can effectively deter defection.

Information

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Government and Opposition Ltd.

Why do business allies (not) defect from a political regime? An emerging scholarship shows that co-opted businesses face high political risks, such as re-nationalization and ownership turnover (Betz and Pond Reference Betz and Pond2023; Resimic Reference Resimic2021). Especially in times of economic crisis, the autocrat may limit the distribution of spoils and prey on his allies to extract rents (Blaydes Reference Blaydes and In Shih2020: 23).Footnote 1 In response, as a formidable social group, the business elite could turn their backs on him. Their defection could be disruptive and consequential – they could mobilize resources for the opposition, stage anti-regime protests or leak compromising information about the regime (Arriola Reference Arriola2013; Junisbai Reference Junisbai2012; Radnitz Reference Radnitz2012; Rithmire Reference Rithmire2023). Yet, on average, the business elite rarely defect (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2023).

One explanation highlights the role of autocratic institutions. An extensive body of scholarship unpacks how authoritarian institutions help resolve credible commitment problems, expand the time horizon for power-sharing arrangements and limit the dictator’s predatory behaviour (Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Wilson and Wright Reference Wilson and Wright2017). Business allies are indeed co-opted through institutions, such as legislative bodies. They seek political office to protect their business interests under a weak regime of private property (Hou Reference Hou2019; Szakonyi Reference Szakonyi2020). However, this institutional account does not fully capture the effect of one type of co-optation on elite defection – what I call patrimonial.

Patrimonial co-optation refers to informal/personal ties the business elite develop with the political office-holders (Kung and Ma Reference Kung and Ma2018). In return for preferential treatment and privileged access to public resources, the business allies offer material benefits to the dictator, which are deployed to help him win the electoral game or make his family rich. In this quid pro quo relationship, the dictator exerts high discretionary power over how rents are distributed. Spoils are allocated to business allies by the central authority without any power-sharing mechanisms (Meng et al. Reference Meng, Paine and Powell2023: 157). That is precisely why patrimonial co-optation is a losing game for the business elite. Once co-opted patrimonially, business allies are less likely to defect, even if they become a punch-bag for the autocrat during economic downturns.

There are two interrelated mechanisms at play. First, there would be a substantive financial loss for defecting businesspeople conceding their privileged market position. The cost of their defection would multiply by the extent of their co-optation to the regime. Second, the dictator has the upper hand in this crony relationship because the corrupt dealings of business allies render them vulnerable to public backlash, tarnish their reputation and hinder their ability to cooperate with opposition forces (Sinanoglu Reference Sinanoglu2023). The dictator can legally hold their history of corruption against his allies-turned-enemies (Zhang Reference Zhang2021), and most importantly, mobilize anti-business public sentiment to justify such repression as an anti-corruption crackdown (Zhu and Zhang Reference Zhu and Zhang2017). That would especially be the case for regimes with a strong propaganda apparatus that could leverage such financial coercion to manufacture public support during economic downturns. Overall, the loss of lucrative co-optative status and the lack of public support are strong deterrents against defection without institutional commitment devices. In sum, with patrimonial co-optation, the dictator can substantially lower the risk of the defection of one major social group without any institutional concessions.

I formalize this strategic dynamic in a simplified bargaining game between the dictator and his business allies. I argue that under high levels of patrimonial co-optation and during major sovereign debt crises, the business elite are less likely to oppose the regime. I test these ideas using a country-year-level dataset of 76 countries from 1992 to 2019. The results show that co-optation through corrupt exchanges with the executive substantively decreases the odds of business opposition. The suppressing effect of such informal co-optation on business opposition is partly mediated through the government’s control over the media landscape.

This article’s contributions are twofold: First, despite a large body of scholarly work on the role of institutions, we still do not know much about the effectiveness of co-optation without power-sharing arrangements (Gerschewski Reference Gerschewski2023: 96). I offer evidence that patrimonial co-optation as an informal, non-institutional strategy can tilt the balance of power in favour of the dictator and prevent his business allies from credibly threatening him. Second, I show that even though economic crises may exacerbate the risk of elite defection under autocracies (Del Río Reference Del Río2022; Reuter and Szakonyi Reference Reuter and Szakonyi2019), that may not necessarily apply to all elite groups or economic crises.

The article is organized as follows: First, I lay out a theoretical framework for elite defection and patrimonial co-optation. Then I present a simplified formal model of bargaining to derive the hypothesis, followed by an empirical assessment.

Business opposition to dictators

Businesspeople develop personal ties with government officials to protect their assets under a weak property rights regime (Kung and Ma Reference Kung and Ma2018). They perceive such informal and personal connections as safeguards against state predation (Frye Reference Frye2017: 69). More than safety measures, these personal connections also come with lucrative opportunities, and proximity to political power pays off. Connected companies benefit from trade protection (Malik and Eibl Reference Malik, Eibl, Diwan, Malik and Atiyas2019), enjoy relaxed regulatory oversight and tax immunity (Rijkers et al. Reference Rijkers, Arouri and Baghdadi2017), receive favourable treatment in courts (Xu Reference Xu2020) and take the lion’s share of public contracts (Çeviker Gürakar and Bircan Reference Çeviker Gürakar, Bircan, In Diwan, Malik and Atiyas2019; Lu and Wang Reference Lu and Wang2023). They use these privileges to enhance their market position, reflected in higher profit rates and equity values (Diwan et al. Reference Diwan, Keefer and Schiffbauer2020). Autocrats also target foreign businesses to eject them from the market and create monopolies for their cronies, as Viktor Orbán’s government did in Hungary against foreign companies with special price caps and tax rates, especially operating in the retail and banking industries (Savage Reference Savage2022).

It takes two to tango – these crony relationships are quid pro quo. The dictator’s business allies must repay their fair share of what they earn from these arrangements. These proceeds are, in turn, used to fund prestigious mega projects to boost the dictator’s popularity, buy out media outlets to erect a propaganda apparatus, or simply make the ruling family rich (Adly Reference Adly2023: 422; Arat and Pamuk Reference Arat and Pamuk2019: 107). Incumbent autocrats amass wealth with their discretionary power over public goods and arbitrary application of formal rules. One of the many illustrative cases is the sheer size of the Ben Ali family’s business empire at the end of their rule, constituting 14.7% of all net private-sector profits in Tunisia (Arouri et al. Reference Arouri, Baghdadi, Rijkers, In Diwan, Malik and Atiyas2019: 178).

Such quid pro quo presents one co-optative tactic of authoritarian political control (Hassan et al. Reference Hassan, Mattingly and Nugent2022) – patrimonial co-optation. Under this economic order, the business elite secure privileged access to state resources in exchange for tangible benefits accrued to their patron. By patrimonialism, I mean particularistic and selectively enforced transactions: The incumbent wields high discretionary power over a centralized distribution of rents, and the executive control over economic assets is highly personalized. Svolik (Reference Svolik2012: 170) calls this ‘co-optation via transfers’, Gerschewski (Reference Gerschewski2023: 105) ‘informal co-optation’, Josua (Reference Josua2016: 40) ‘material co-optation’, or Hale (Reference Hale2014: 10) calls it ‘patronal politics’. I use ‘patrimonial’ to put more emphasis on this material exchange’s vertically structured, personalist and particularistic nature. The central premise here is that spoils are allocated to business allies without power-sharing via concessions (Meng et al. Reference Meng, Paine and Powell2023: 157), and the dictator appropriates the state apparatus to target productive assets for allocation or confiscation purposes as he deems fit.

This type of co-optation is not a cosy relationship. Autocrats are not perfect agents of economic elites (Albertus and Gay Reference Albertus and Gay2017: 627) – they prey on their allies and consolidate their rule at the peril of their support coalition. An emerging scholarship highlights the downside of co-optation for businesses: politically connected firms face a higher risk of re-nationalization, ownership turnover and decline in stock value, to cite a few (Barraza et al. Reference Barraza, Rossi and Ruzzier2022; Betz and Pond Reference Betz and Pond2023; Li Reference Li2023; Resimic Reference Resimic2021).

The political risk for co-opted businesses gets more pronounced during financial crises. Resource constraints may jeopardize patronage networks under personalist dictatorships, forcing the dictators to cut back spending (Escribà-Folch and Wright Reference Escribà-Folch and Wright2010: 339). In response to declining resources, the dictator may need to shrink the winning coalition’s size or extract rents from allies in order to survive (Blaydes Reference Blaydes and In Shih2020: 23).

Sovereign debt crises, in particular, put regime durability at risk. A sovereign default is when a government does not pay back the principal or interest on its debt by the scheduled deadline. Unlike the extant scholarship on elite defection that uses gross domestic product (GDP) growth rates to identify periods of economic downturn (Del Río Reference Del Río2022: 2265; Djuve and Knutsen Reference Djuve, Knutsen, In Dallago and Casagrande2022; Reuter and Gandhi Reference Reuter and Gandhi2011: 93), I focus on sovereign debt crises when autocrats are under severe fiscal duress. It is because autocrats may survive through short-term economic fluctuations (Shih Reference Shih2020: 11) – GDP growth, unemployment and inflation rates reflect the general economic conditions of a country, but they do not directly indicate the incumbent’s fiscal capacity to ride out a crisis. Take the case of Turkey: the Turkish economy has been experiencing a currency crisis since 2018 and serious hyperinflation since early 2021. However, the Justice and Development Party (AKP) government has been able to maintain patronage networks to a certain degree and roll out massive programmes with severe fiscal burdens like the FX-linked deposit programme or the law on the early retirement scheme, for which the government had to earmark billions of dollars (Kozok Reference Kozok2022). Sovereign debt crises have serious implications for businesses: for example, Sinanoglu (Reference Sinanoglu2024) finds that politically connected firms that have secured a public contract are more likely to be financially repressed, even more so during sovereign debt crises. In other words, autocrats prey on their allies when push comes to shove.

How would business allies respond to such financial repression by the autocrat? The business elite’s support for the dictator would be contingent on whether their interests are being served or not (Bellin Reference Bellin2000). One key insight from the scholarship is that high uncertainty about future access to spoils increases the likelihood of defection. For instance, Hale (Reference Hale2014: 66) argues that patronal systems are particularly crisis-prone because of the expectations mechanism: if elites believe the patron will remain in charge, few will challenge him; but if the dictator fails to project public popularity and presidential dominance, elites begin to doubt his future grip on power and become more inclined to abandon him. In a similar vein, Reuter and Szakonyi (Reference Reuter and Szakonyi2019) show that defections are more likely when the regime lacks electoral popularity and there are few institutional constraints on the leader, leaving elites with little assurance of future spoils. Economic crises or election cycles can further facilitate coordination against the regime (Del Río Reference Del Río2022; Reuter and Gandhi Reference Reuter and Gandhi2011), especially when elites have suffered from the dictator’s arbitrary actions, such as the expropriation of business assets by members of the ruling circle (Junisbai Reference Junisbai2012: 901).

There is enough evidence to show how business defection could be consequential, from different contexts like Kenya, Ukraine, Tunisia or Kyrgyzstan (Sinanoglu et al. Reference Sinanoglu, Way and Levitsky2025). As a formidable social group, the business elite can allocate financial resources for mobilizing the opposition and staging anti-regime protests (Arriola Reference Arriola2013: 33; Radnitz Reference Radnitz2012). The ‘disruptive power’ the business elite hold stems from their connectedness to the regime – the more connected they are, the more likely they are to possess compromising material – kompromat – that can endanger the political elites (Rithmire Reference Rithmire2023: 107). Indeed, once leaked, corruption can be politically costly for an autocrat (Carothers Reference Carothers2023).

Despite this disruptive and structural power, business opposition to autocrats is rare. According to V-Dem data (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2023), in 2022, in only 30% of electoral autocracies were the business elite in opposition (mobilized or not), and only in five cases, actively mobilized against the regime. Though the number of electoral autocracies where the business elite have been in opposition has increased over the years, businesspeople are more likely to join the authoritarian support coalition than the opposition (see Figure B1 and Figure B3 in the Supplementary Material).

One potential explanation is the presence of autocratic institutions. An extensive body of scholarship shows that constraining institutions may help resolve the dictator’s commitment problem of credibly sharing spoils with the elite, limit his confiscatory behaviour, regularize his interactions with the elite and facilitate compliance (Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011; Escribà-Folch Reference Escribà-Folch2009; Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Wilson and Wright Reference Wilson and Wright2017; Wright Reference Wright2008). Entrepreneurs indeed seek opportunities within formal institutions, such as seats in legislative bodies, to protect their business interests (Hou Reference Hou2019; Szakonyi Reference Szakonyi2020).

However, the institutional account does not explain the full picture. We still do not know much about the impact of non-institutionalized co-optation on elite defection, that is, quid pro quo without such commitment devices (Gerschewski Reference Gerschewski2023: 96). For example, a handpicked group of businesspeople has always been taken on official foreign visits with Turkish President Erdogan’s plane to secure contracts abroad. Being ‘on board’ has been an indication of how close these businesspeople are to Erdogan. One example is the CEO of a large real estate company in Turkey – he has been ‘buddies’ with Erdogan for years. He has hosted him multiple times at his resort in Antalya for vacation and publicly expressed his support for the 2017 referendum that solidified autocratization in Turkey. In return, the Ministry of Environment and Urbanization worked around legal injunctions and environmental regulations to give him a real estate deal in Istanbul worth a billion dollars (T24 2020). Another example is a businessperson Erdogan famously owed TL2 million in 2018 (Duvar 2018). Rumoured to be an old friend of the Erdogan family and having had business dealings with them, his company has contracted lucrative real estate projects in national parks despite public uproar against their environmental destruction.

To add another example, back in 1994, Orbán knew patrimonial co-optation could work for his regime in Hungary and prevent defection. Criticizing the former prime minister, József Antall, during an interview, he said:

He should have identified the 8–10 major businessmen … to become Hungary’s leading tycoons. And these people should have been supported …, simply by providing them with banking contacts. … [H]e should have built personal relationships with [them], [who could] have exploited [their relationship with the Hungarian prime minister and his innermost circle] as competitive edge in the market. … You see, not a single tycoon stuck with [him] during the election campaign. They all switched sides. … It could have gone differently had the ties been sufficiently strengthened before. (Sebők and Simons Reference Sebők and Simons2022: 1635)

It might work for the autocrat, but patrimonial co-optation is a losing game for the business elite. While they pursue these personal connections to reap benefits and hedge against predatory behaviour, they do not have many manoeuvres for an exit strategy once locked in. The more dense these crony relationships, the less likely they are to defect, even without constraining institutions. Even when the dictator preys on them to extract rent in times of crisis, the balance of power is tilted in favour of the dictator in this co-optative relationship.

There are two interrelated reasons why the cards are stacked against the business elite. First, the more financially dependent the business allies are on these patronage networks, the more they would lose should they confront the regime. That is especially the case in late developing economies where state contracts constitute a major source of revenue. In other words, the cost of defection amplifies with the extent of co-optation. When rents are concentrated and distributed centrally by the executive authority, and there are limited economic prospects outside the system, defection becomes a huge gamble (Markowitz Reference Markowitz2017: 109).

Second, once a businessperson exploits their connections to attain economic leverage, they make themselves susceptible to future legal repression and criminal charges (Zhang Reference Zhang2021), as they lose their public support and tarnish their reputation, leading to coordination problems with opposition forces. The autocrat can galvanize public support for repressive acts by presenting them as crackdowns on corruption with intense anti-business and anti-corruption public sentiment. That would especially be the case for regimes with a strong propaganda apparatus, which would blame corrupt business allies for the country’s economic difficulties. Their financial coercion would resonate with the public and boost the autocrat’s popularity, despite there being a severe economic downturn. For instance, Sinanoglu (Reference Sinanoglu2023) shows that people are more likely to condone the financial repression of co-opted businesspeople than others during economic downturns, if they owe their entrepreneurial success to the regime and are perceived as rent seekers responsible for the economic crisis. Overall, the risk of severe financial loss and potential public backlash thus serve as strong deterrents against defection.

The reasons for the rarity of business defection under patrimonial capitalism also explain why business allies are ineffective in ousting the dictator, even when they defect. Take the case of Lajos Simicska. He has been cited as one of the major reasons behind Orbán’s electoral success. In exchange for lucrative government contracts for his construction company, his media outlets lent Orbán indulgent support. But in the aftermath of a public disagreement between them, when Simicska publicly humiliated Orbán because of the government’s crippling advertisement tax, he defected from the regime (Kovách et al. Reference Kovách2022: 266). His media outlets published damning stories and leaked information about the extent of corruption under Orbán’s regime. They were ineffective: a few weeks after these revelations, Orbán’s party won a landslide victory in the 2018 parliamentary elections. Despite his defection, Simicska was not publicly popular due to his history of corrupt dealings with the regime. He could not find allies among the opposition parties, as they tried to distance themselves from him, rejecting claims that Simicska was funding their parties (Andras and Szabo Reference Andras and Szabo2019). In the end, it was not a fair fight for Simicska. He lost his media empire, and his construction company was banned from public procurement. He was practically replaced by a childhood friend of Orbán, Lőrinc Mészáros, who became a billionaire with dizzying speed.

In the next section, I formalize these strategic interactions between the dictator and his business allies, and model the businesses’ cost of defection and the dictator’s cost of repression as a function of degree of co-optation and the extent of anti-corruption public sentiment.

Model

There are two players: the Dictator (D) and his Business Ally (B). The prehistory of this escalation/bargaining game is that under a sovereign debt crisis, D decides to shift the financial burden to B. Without loss of generality, I set this cost to −1.

The game begins with B deciding on how to respond. B may yield to D’s pressure and accept the fiscal burden. Then, B and D receive a payoff of (−1, 0), respectively. Alternatively, B may decide to oppose the government. Should B oppose the regime, then the conflict becomes public. In response, D either doubles down with repression or concedes to B. If D concedes, then he receives a payoff of (−k p) while B’s payoff is (0). k denotes the additional cost that D pays upon B escalating the conflict, k ∈ (0, 1). p denotes the intensity of anti-business/anti-corruption public sentiment as p ∈ Z+. Higher values of p imply more public hostility towards co-opted businesses. When D yields, there is an additional cost of public backlash to concessions.

If D decides to double down, B faces two options: yielding to D’s pressure or escalating further to challenge the regime. If B concedes, then his payoff is (−1 k). In addition to the burden of the debt crisis, B incurred k for escalating the conflict. On the other hand, when B yields to D’s coercion, D’s payoff is (k + p). Essentially, D extracts an extra k from successfully repressing B following escalation on top of the electoral popularity of the repressive act.

If B continues to defy the regime, his payoff is (−rbc). r b indicates the cost of open confrontation with D with a uniform probability distribution. c refers to B’s degree of co-optation as c ∈ Z+. The higher c, the more co-opted is B. In other words, the more engaged B is in quid pro quo with D, the more he would lose. When B confronts the regime, D’s payoff is (−rdc). rd expresses the cost of antagonism against one of his allies with a uniform probability distribution. The cost gets more pronounced with higher degrees of B’s co-optation. The more entrenched crony networks between B and D, the more likely B possesses leverage against D. The extensive form of this game is depicted in Figure 1.

Figure 1. Game Tree

The model presents the cost of defection and repression decisions as a function of the degree of co-optation and public sentiment. The model also considers the popularity of repressive acts against crony elites. Under a setting of incomplete information, both B and D observe their own relative costs but not their rival’s; however, their probability distributions, Fb and Fd, are common knowledge. The solution concept for the game is perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE). The equilibrium strategies are solved for rb and rd and their beliefs over each other’s strategies. Proofs for complete and incomplete information and the equilibrium strategies are available in the Supplementary Material.

In the subgame perfect equilibrium, the model yields the following predictions. First, even for relatively high costs of repression for the Dictator, the probability that the Business Ally’s opposition induces the Dictator to yield is small; the equilibrium path typically escalates to open confrontation. In subgames where the Dictator’s decision to repress depends on the degree of co-optation, if the crisis cost is sufficiently low and anti-business public sentiment is moderately high, the Dictator’s probability of repression dominates the Business Ally’s probability of opposition. Second, comparative statics show that the Business Ally’s equilibrium probability of opposition decreases as anti-corruption public sentiment intensifies and as the degree of co-optation rises. Last, when the fiscal crisis cost is low, and the Dictator’s decision is independent of the co-optation level, the Dictator doubles down with certainty, given a modest level of anti-business public sentiment. In other words, the Dictator enjoys a strategic advantage in this co-optative arrangement.

Hypothesis 1: Under high levels of patrimonial co-optation, the business elite are less likely to oppose the regime.

Empirical setting

To probe this hypothesis, I use a country-year-level panel dataset of 76 countries (see Table B1) from 1992 to 2019, based on the V-Dem dataset (Coppedge et al. Reference Coppedge2023). First, I excluded small, non-independent and oil-rich regimes with oil income per capita higher than USD500. Resource-rich regimes can fiscally survive through debt crises thanks to accumulated oil wealth in the state coffers. In the regimes under scrutiny here, governments face severe debt crises when their hands are forced to downsize the winning coalition, so the political risks are real and substantive. Second, the listed countries experienced authoritarianism, but at least with one multiparty election with high competition. The lack of active opposition by businesses to the autocratic regime would be the main expectation in closed, opaque regimes like Saudi Arabia or Cuba. The scope condition here is that the business elite could afford political manoeuvres to defect to the opposition. Last, the analysis focuses on the post-Cold War period, when businesses started to play a major political role, especially following market liberalization.

How significant is the business community in this sample of cases? First, V-Dem measures which groups are the most powerful in affecting regime duration and change. In the selected time period, in 14 countries, the business elite is cited at least once as the most powerful group. In addition, a descriptive analysis of private sector investment data by the World Bank shows that in 2022 the average gross fixed private capital investment constitutes roughly 17% of GDP in a subset of these cases, depending on data availability. In some notable cases, this share exceeds 25% of GDP (see Table B3). Overall, the governments would have the motivation to politically control the business community for the purposes of regime durability.

There has been a major debate regarding the accuracy of expert-coded measures; however, expert-coded data can still be highly informative (Bergeron-Boutin et al. Reference Bergeron-Boutin2024). This is especially true for phenomena like business opposition to dictators with little or no ‘smoking guns’. The business elite’s active and mobilized opposition is rare, and it is challenging to identify ‘objective’ comparable indicators across countries. Thus, expert insights are crucial for making sense of such opposition dynamics that go on behind closed doors.

Dependent variables

V-Dem data code different social groups that pose major opposition to the regime, including the business elite. This measure indicates whether a significant share of the business elite – mobilized or not – both want and could be able to threaten and oust the regime under favourable circumstances. I generate a binary indicator of business opposition to the regime at two different thresholds.Footnote 2

There are two noteworthy trends. First, compared to the early 1990s, the number of countries where the business elite are in opposition has almost doubled (see Figure B1). That said, business opposition is still a rare phenomenon within electoral autocracies. Only in a handful of cases have the business elite consistently been cited as a major opposition group, such as in Kyrgyzstan, Togo, Madagascar and Guinea-Bissau (see Figure B2). Though rare, their opposition may be consequential. For example, the data illustrates the business elite’s switch to opposition in 2010 in Tunisia.

V-Dem data also code whether the regime relies on the business elite to maintain power as a support group and, if they were to withdraw their support, whether it would increase the odds of regime change or not. I create a binary indicator of business support for the regime as an alternative measure of state–business relations.Footnote 3 In 2019, the business elite were part of the support coalition in almost half of the countries in the dataset (see Figure B3 and B4).

Explanatory variables

As a proxy for patrimonial co-optative relationships between the executive and business elite, I use an interval measure of executive bribery and corrupt exchanges in the V-Dem dataset. The indicator reports how routinely the executive or their agents offer favours in return for material inducements.Footnote 4 Consistent with the formal model and the conceptual framework for co-optation, this measure exhibits to what degree the executive is engaged with quid pro quo. As an alternative proxy for co-optation, I also use V-Dem’s neopatrimonialism index. The index measures the extent of unconstrained personalistic rule with clientelist political relationships and the use of public resources for legitimation. The index includes indicators on vote buying, particularistic good provisions, the lack of judicial constraints, and executive embezzlement, theft and corruption.Footnote 5

To identify periods of sovereign debt crisis, I use Nguyen et al.’s (Reference Nguyen, Castro and Wood2022) global dataset. They operationalize a debt crisis with the following conditions: the total defaults exceed 1% of GDP in at least three consecutive years or 7% of GDP. Their operationalization has two distinguishing features. First, it covers both external and domestic debt defaults. Second, the identification criteria exclude negligible defaults. Almost 80% of the countries in the data experienced a debt crisis at least once in the covered period (Figure B5).

Covariates

In alternative model specifications, I use two indicators from the V-Dem dataset to control for the government’s level of repression that may confound the relationship between co-optation and business opposition (Bove and Rivera Reference Bove and Rivera2015). One interval indicator measures whether there is freedom from torture; that is, whether the public authorities respect bodily integrity. Another one measures freedom from political killings, which refers to instances where the political authorities employ lethal force to eliminate political opponents.

I include several indicators from the V-Dem dataset to gauge how constrained the executive authority is. Institutional or political constraints may hamper rent-seeking, drive compliance with the regime and serve as devices of credible commitment between the business elite and the dictator. An index measure of the judicial constraints on the executive is included, which covers the executive’s compliance with the constitution and the independent judiciary. In alternative model specifications, I also incorporate an index of legislative constraints on the executive authority, which measures the extent to which the legislature and government agencies are capable of exercising oversight over the executive. As a proxy of institutional co-optation to be used for robustness checks, I include an indicator of access to state jobs, and whether those positions are restricted only to those with affiliations with a political group. I introduce a measure of opposition party autonomy to account for electoral constraints. Higher political competition (and losing electoral support) may shift the regime’s co-optation strategy towards the opposition (Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2007). This measure shows whether opposition parties are allowed, and either selected or co-opted by the ruling regime. In alternative models, I also add the polyarchy score as a control.

State control over the economy may also confound the relationship between co-optation and business support. In countries with a high degree of economic liberalization, the business elite would be better endowed – the dispersion of financial resources may dismantle patronage networks and facilitate the opposition’s mobilization (Sinanoglu et al. Reference Sinanoglu, Way and Levitsky2025). I add a measure of state ownership of the economy from the V-Dem dataset that gauges to what extent valuable capital is owned or directly controlled by the state. There might also be an incumbency advantage: co-optation networks will likely be entrenched with longer tenures. To control for such temporal effects, I include a scaled indicator of regime duration.

I use several proxies for the social support/opposition and mobilization for/against the regime. Under resource constraints, the dictator faces a dilemma between co-opting the elite and containing popular mobilizations (Bove et al. Reference Bove, Platteau and Sekeris2017). Increased pressure from below might prompt the dictator to purge the elite and shrink the size of the winning coalition (Dodlova and Lucas Reference Dodlova and Lucas2021). On the other hand, popular mobilizations and increased grassroots demand for democratization might also shape the business elite’s decision to defect (Andrews and Honig Reference Andrews and Honig2019; Casper and Tyson Reference Casper and Tyson2014). In alternative specifications, using V-Dem data, I control for the size of pro-democracy and pro-autocracy mass mobilizations. I also include two measures of the size of support coalition and opposition groups, respectively. Last, I control for the degree of polarization. Dictators may employ polarization as an electoral strategy to consolidate their power base and delineate frictions within the business community (Sinanoglu Reference Sinanoglu2023).

Statistical models

Business opposition is rare. Only in 15% of country-year periods are the business elite opposed to the regime. The analysis of such binary rare event data poses methodological challenges. The fundamental issue here is that with fixed effects (FE) estimators, parameter estimates are only generated from units that experience the event, inflating the baseline event risk and biasing the marginal effects. As a remedy, I apply a generalized linear model (GLM) with penalized maximum likelihood (PL) conditional FE estimator as proposed by Cook et al. (Reference Cook, Hays and Franzese2020).Footnote 6 For robustness checks, I also estimate generalized linear mixed models (GLMM) with random intercepts at country and year levels, as well as fixed intercepts for each year to capture year-specific variation (Schmidt-Catran and Fairbrother Reference Schmidt-Catran and Fairbrother2016). Last, I run linear FE models as well.Footnote 7

Main findings

Figure 2 shows the exponentiated coefficients of explanatory variables from the main GLM PL-FE models with executive corrupt exchanges as the measure of co-optation. Table C1 in the Supplementary Material reports full regression tables for the main models. Results with alternative model specifications with the best model fit are reported in Tables C2 and C4. Figure 3 illustrates the average marginal effect of co-optation on business support and defection.

Notes: Co-optation Is operationalized with executive corrupt exchanges. All models include a lagged dependent variable (DV). Full regression tables are reported in Table C1 in the Supplementary Material.

Figure 2. The Exponentiated Coefficients from the Main GLM PL-FE Models for Business Support and Opposition

Notes: Co-optation is operationalized with executive corrupt exchanges.

Figure 3. The Average Marginal Effect of Co-optation on Business Support and Opposition

The higher degrees of co-optation are significantly associated with a lower likelihood of business opposition. This finding is robust to different specifications. The effect size is also substantive: Depending on the model specification, one standard deviation increase in the level of executive corrupt exchanges decreases the odds of opposition by 55–69.6%. Similarly, co-optation is statistically and positively associated with business support for the regime, which is a consistent finding across different models. The marginal effects on the likelihood of support are also considerable: one standard deviation increase in the level of co-optation increases the odds of support by a factor of 2.59 to 3.16, depending on the model. In other words, co-optation may have symmetrical effects on business opposition and support.

Experiencing a debt crisis is negatively associated with the probability of opposition only in some models. The marginal effect of one unit increase on the odds of opposition is as high as 59%, but the coefficient estimate is statistically insignificant for some model specifications, and it is not robust across different model specifications for the main measure of co-optation. Debt crisis is not significantly correlated with business support for the regime in the main regressions.

I discuss other covariates in the Appendix.

Robustness checks

Robustness checks largely confirm the main findings. To ensure the consistency of these findings, first, I use a different proxy for the main explanatory variable, co-optation: neo-patrimonialism index (see Table C3 and Table C5). The results remain robust: higher degrees of co-optation are substantively associated with a lower likelihood of business opposition and a higher likelihood of business support. A debt crisis is mostly negatively correlated with business opposition, though insignificant for business support. I also use a more conservative threshold for classifying cases of business opposition and support (see Table C10 and Table C11). Both debt crisis and co-optation are substantively and negatively correlated with the odds of business opposition but statistically insignificant for the regressions on business support.

As an alternative estimation strategy, I apply GLMM (see Table C6 and Table C7). The results remain the same with the co-optation measure: it significantly decreases business opposition, and boosts support. The estimate of the debt crisis is insignificant for business opposition, but largely significant and positive for business support. In addition, I also use the interval measures of business support and opposition for linear FE regressions (see Table C8 and Table C9). The effect of the debt crisis is insignificant in these regressions. Co-optation is positively, significantly and robustly correlated with business support, but it is largely insignificant for business opposition. Table C12 reports the main results without lagged dependent variables, and Tables C13 and C14 report the findings with an interaction of co-optation and debt crisis. The results remain largely the same. Table C15 demonstrates the results of the main regressions, including a proxy of institutional co-optation, and patrimonial co-optation remains significant both for business support and opposition.

Mediation analysis

One potential mechanism for the lack of business opposition to autocrats is their tarnished reputation and a growing anti-business sentiment. The public often sees the co-opted business elite as corrupt (Sinanoglu Reference Sinanoglu2023). Autocrats may exploit their lack of popularity by framing financial coercion as part of a broader anti-corruption campaign. Especially governments with effective propaganda machinery and extensive control over the media landscape would find it easier to blame their business allies for the country’s economic hardships. Financial crackdowns on these figures would not just reap short-term windfalls for the regime, but also resonate with the public and boost the autocrat’s popularity during an economic crisis.

To assess whether the effect of patrimonial co-optation on business opposition is mediated by state propaganda, I use an indicator from V-Dem that shows whether major print and broadcast media represent only the government’s perspective. I estimated a Bayesian causal mediation model with one-period lags, and country- and year-level random intercepts, controlling for regime duration, state ownership of the economy, judicial constraints, the regime’s support group size, and level of polarization. Figure 4 presents the posterior distributions of direct, indirect through government control over media, and total effects of co-optation with 95% credible intervals. The direct effect remains substantial even when accounting for the mediator. There is also a credible indirect effect via propaganda (median = −0.10), suggesting that co-optation partially tames the business actors through the government’s control over the media (see also Figure C1).

Figure 4. Posterior Distributions of Effect Size with 95% Credible Intervals, Bayesian Causal Mediation Analysis with Weakly Informative Priors

Discussion

Recent studies shed light on why politically connected businesses face severe consequences, especially during economic crises, and get the thin end of the stick (Resimic Reference Resimic2021; Sinanoglu Reference Sinanoglu2024). And yet, the business elite rarely defect. Given their structural and potentially disruptive power, this acquiescence is unexpected. This lack of opposition stems partly from the security autocratic institutions offer, which credibly constrain the ruler’s predation and expand the time horizons (Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011; Wright Reference Wright2008). However, this institutional account does not capture the full picture.

I argue that patrimonial co-optation – informal ties between the business elite and political leaders – discourages defection by providing benefits in exchange for support, making defection disadvantageous due to the threat of repression with anti-business public sentiment and significant financial losses. In other words, even without institutional concessions and credible power-sharing arrangements, the dictator can effectively deter the business elite from defection using the informal exchange of material benefits as a tool of political control.

I formalize this strategic dynamic as a bargaining game and empirically test it using a country-year-level dataset of 76 countries between 1992 and 2019. The results demonstrate how patrimonial co-optation effectively maintains business elite support for autocratic regimes, even amid severe economic downturns. Even though economic crises may increase the risk of elite defection under autocracies (Reuter and Szakonyi Reference Reuter and Szakonyi2019), that may not necessarily apply to the dictator’s co-opted business allies. The effect of co-optation is also partly mediated by the state’s extensive control over the media landscape and propaganda apparatus.

Why do these powerful business actors not invest in institutional constraints or collective action instead of securing personal privileges? The reason is that, in non-oil economies, rent opportunities are limited, forcing business groups to compete for a smaller pie. As the size of the winning coalition grows, it becomes more difficult to stage collective action, as seen in the conflicts among real estate developers over public tenders in Hong Kong (Wong Reference Wong2015: 15). Some businesspeople fight for political and institutional guarantees against state predation so that they can compete with those closest to the dictator and his inner circle (Junisbai Reference Junisbai2012: 902), but even then, the returns of holding office decline when faced with more competitors in power (Szakonyi Reference Szakonyi2020: 183). Therefore, businesspeople choose to develop personal connections with the autocrat under patrimonial economies, where the dictator has top-down and personal control over the distribution of resources.

What, then, is the optimal strategy for the business elite under authoritarian regimes? On the one hand, they develop crony networks for a reason. These connections may improve their market position against competitors in an imperfect market economy. They gain access to lucrative state contracts, avoid paying taxes and evade regulations – opportunities their competitors may grab if they do not. On the other hand, mounting evidence suggests that political connectedness also brings about serious political risks for businesses (Betz and Pond Reference Betz and Pond2023; Li Reference Li2023; Resimic Reference Resimic2021). Is co-optation then worth the risk?

I think co-optation pays off – until it does not. Co-opted businesses lose their political edge when it matters the most: during economic crises. As a robust elite group, they could pressure the incumbent government to pursue certain economic reforms and policies, threaten exit in case of financial repression, and coordinate with opposition parties against the regime. However, that is not much the case for the co-opted business elite. If they criticize the regime’s policies, the tax agency can knock on their doors the next day without much public backlash (Sinanoglu Reference Sinanoglu2023). The more dependent they become on the state for financial gains and the more corrupt deals they get entangled with, the more leverage the dictator holds against them. The co-opted business elite lose their credible threat of exit. They lose their public credibility and the ability to coordinate with opposition forces.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2025.10021.

Data availability

Replication materials will be made available at: https://github.com/semuhi/business-opposition.

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Lucan Way, Timothy Frye, Antoinette Handley, Kanta Murali and Michael Donnelly for useful advice. The usual caveats apply.

Footnotes

1 Throughout the text, I use he/him pronouns to refer to dictators, as historically, the overwhelming majority are men.

2 This dichotomous indicator is averaged over the number of coders. I use 0.5 as the cutoff point to identify cases of opposition. I use 0.75 as the threshold for a more conservative estimate.

3 Similarly, I use 0.5 as the cutoff point to identify cases of support and 0.75 as a more conservative measure for robustness checks.

4 In the original data, the higher this value, the less likely executive bribery. I reversed the order of levels to make it more intuitive.

5 One limitation of these measures is that it is one-sided in the sense that it demonstrates the autocrat’s willingness to engage with bribery for the purposes of political control, however, does not necessarily reflect the business point of view. That said, in the cases under scrutiny, most of which are late-developing economies, access to public bids and other state resources constitutes a huge source of revenue for firms, so much so that it is impossible for the firms to grow without them. In other words, developing political connections is the business survival mode against both competitors and state predation.

6 All models include a lagged DV and fixed effects (FE) to alleviate endogeneity concerns. For business support, I run GLM FE models without penalized likelihood for the main results. Robustness checks are reported with penalized likelihood.

7 Note that there is no uncertainty estimate for the original scale of DVs in the V-Dem dataset, unlike other coded variables. This interval measure simply shows the share of coders who agree that a particular group is supportive or in opposition. These model specifications also include a lagged DV.

References

Adly, A (2023) Disempowerment without Expropriation: Egypt’s Old Oligarchy under Sisi. British Journal of Middle Eastern Studies 50(2), 410435. https://doi.org/10.1080/13530194.2021.1975533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albertus, M and Gay, V (2017) Unlikely Democrats: Economic Elite Uncertainty under Dictatorship and Support for Democratization. American Journal of Political Science 61(3), 624641. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andras, P and Szabo, A (2019) Inside the Fall of the Oligarch Who Turned against Viktor Orban. Direkt36, 14 January.Google Scholar
Andrews, S and Honig, L (2019) Elite Defection and Grassroots Democracy under Competitive Authoritarianism: Evidence from Burkina Faso. Democratization 26(4), 626644. https://doi.org/10.1080/13510347.2019.1566322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arat, Y and Pamuk, S (2019) Turkey between Democracy and Authoritarianism. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781139022385CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arouri, H, Baghdadi, L and Rijkers, B (2019) State Capture in Ben Ali’s Tunisia. In Diwan, I, Malik, A and Atiyas, I (eds), Crony Capitalism in the Middle East. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 173204.10.1093/oso/9780198799870.003.0007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arriola, LR (2013) Multiethnic Coalitions in Africa: Business Financing of Opposition Election Campaigns. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barraza, S, Rossi, MA and Ruzzier, CA (2022) Sleeping with the Enemy: The Perils of Having the Government on(the)Board. Journal of Comparative Economics 50(3), 641651. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2022.01.005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellin, E (2000) Contingent Democrats: Industrialists, Labor, and Democratization in Late-Developing Countries. World Politics 52(2), 175205. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0043887100002598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergeron-Boutin, O et al. (2024) Expert Bias and Democratic Erosion: Assessing Expert Perceptions of Contemporary American Democracy. PS: Political Science & Politics 57(2), 110. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1049096523000719.Google Scholar
Betz, T and Pond, A (2023) Politically Connected Owners. Comparative Political Studies 56(4), 561595. https://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221109428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, L (2011) Elections and Distributive Politics in Mubarak’s Egypt. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Blaydes, L (2020) The Domestic Political Implications of Economic Sanctions: Evidence from Iraq under Saddam Hussein. In Shih, VC (ed.), Economic Shocks and Authoritarian Stability: Duration, Financial Control, and Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, pp. 2140.Google Scholar
Bove, V, Platteau, J-P and Sekeris, PG (2017) Political Repression in Autocratic Regimes. Journal of Comparative Economics 45(2), 410428. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2016.11.004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bove, V and Rivera, M (2015) Elite Co-optation, Repression, and Coups in Autocracies. International Interactions 41(3), 453479. https://doi.org/10.1080/03050629.2015.1006727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carothers, C (2023) The Autocrat’s Corruption Dilemma. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 58(1), 2238. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casper, BA and Tyson, SA (2014) Popular Protest and Elite Coordination in a Coup d’État. Journal of Politics 76(2), 548564. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022381613001485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Çeviker Gürakar, E and Bircan, T (2019) Political Connections and Public Procurement in Turkey: Evidence from Construction Work Contracts. In Diwan, I, Malik, A and Atiyas, I (eds), Crony Capitalism in the Middle East: Business and Politics from Liberalization to the Arab Spring. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 236262.10.1093/oso/9780198799870.003.0009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cook, SJ, Hays, JC and Franzese, RJ (2020) Fixed Effects in Rare Events Data: A Penalized Maximum Likelihood Solution. Political Science Research and Methods 8(1), 92105. https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2018.40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppedge, M et al. (2023) V-Dem Codebook V13. No. 13. Gothenburg: V-Dem Institute, March. www.v-dem.net.Google Scholar
Del Río, A (2022) Strategic Uncertainty and Elite Defections in Electoral Autocracies: A Cross-National Analysis. Comparative Political Studies 55(13), 22502282. https://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221074273.Google Scholar
Diwan, I, Keefer, P and Schiffbauer, M (2020) Pyramid Capitalism: Cronyism, Regulation, and Firm Productivity in Egypt. Review of International Organizations 15(1), 211246. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-018-9327-2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djuve, VL and Knutsen, CH (2022) How Economic Systems and Performance Influence Regime Change. In Dallago, B and Casagrande, S (eds), The Routledge Handbook of Comparative Economic Systems. New York: Routledge, pp. 563580.10.4324/9781003144366-35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dodlova, M and Lucas, V (2021) Regime Security and Taxation in Autocracies: Who Is Taxed and How? European Journal of Political Economy 67, 115. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2020.101998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duvar (2018) Erdogan’ın 2 Milyon Lira Borclu Oldugu Mehmet Gur Kimdir? 5 July.Google Scholar
Escribà-Folch, A (2009) Do Authoritarian Institutions Mobilize Economic Cooperation? Constitutional Political Economy 20(1), 7193. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9052-6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Escribà-Folch, A and Wright, J (2010) Dealing with Tyranny: International Sanctions and the Survival of Authoritarian Rulers. International Studies Quarterly 54(2), 335359. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2478.2010.00590.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frye, T (2017) Property Rights and Property Wrongs: How Power, Institutions, and Norms Shape Economic Conflict in Russia. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781316661727CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gandhi, J and Przeworski, A (2007) Authoritarian Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats. Comparative Political Studies 40(11), 12791301. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414007305817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschewski, J (2023) The Two Logics of Autocratic Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781009199407CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, HE (2014) Patronal Politics: Eurasian Regime Dynamics in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9781139683524CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hassan, M, Mattingly, D and Nugent, ER (2022) Political Control. Annual Review of Political Science 25(1), 155174. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-051120-013321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hou, Y (2019) The Private Sector in Public Office: Selective Property Rights in China. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781108632522CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Josua, M (2016) Co-Optation Reconsidered: Authoritarian Regime Legitimation Strategies in the Jordanian Arab Spring. Middle East Law and Governance 8(1), 3256. https://doi.org/10.1163/18763375-00801001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Junisbai, B (2012) Improbable but Potentially Pivotal Oppositions: Privatization, Capitalists, and Political Contestation in the Post-Soviet Autocracies. Perspectives on Politics 10(4), 891916. www.jstor.org/stable/23326924.10.1017/S153759271200285XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kovách, I et al. (2022) Dynamics of an Authoritarian System: Hungary, 2010–2021. Vienna: Central European University Press.Google Scholar
Kozok, F (2022) Turkey to Earmark $13 Billion for Early Retirement Ballot Pledge. Bloomberg, 29 December.Google Scholar
Kung, JK and Ma, C (2018) Friends with Benefits: How Political Connections Help to Sustain Private Enterprise Growth in China. Economica 85(337), 4174. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, Z (2023) Connections as Liabilities: The Cost of the Politics–Business Revolving Door in China. British Journal of Political Science 53(4), 12521272. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123422000473.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, S and Wang, H (2023) How Political Connections Exploit Loopholes in Procurement Institutions for Government Contracts: Evidence from China. Governance 36(4), 12051224. https://doi.org/10.1111/gove.12735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malik, A and Eibl, F (2019) The Politics of Trade Protection in North Africa. In Diwan, I, Malik, A and Atiyas, I (eds), Crony Capitalism in the Middle East: Business and Politics from Liberalization to the Arab Spring. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 205235.10.1093/oso/9780198799870.003.0008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markowitz, LP (2017) Beyond Kompromat: Coercion, Corruption, and Deterred Defection in Uzbekistan. Comparative Politics 50(1), 103121. www.jstor.org/stable/26330976.10.5129/001041517821864390CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, A, Paine, J and Powell, R (2023) Authoritarian Power Sharing: Concepts, Mechanisms, and Strategies. Annual Review of Political Science 26(1), 153173. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-052121-020406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nguyen, TC, Castro, V and Wood, J (2022) A New Comprehensive Database of Financial Crises: Identification, Frequency, and Duration. Economic Modelling 108, 145. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radnitz, SB (2012) Weapons of the Wealthy: Predatory Regimes and Elite-Led Protests in Central Asia. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.10.7591/9780801466175CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Resimic, M (2021) Network Ties and the Politics of Renationalization: Embeddedness, Political-Business Relations, and Renationalization in Post-Milosevic Serbia. Comparative Political Studies 54(1), 179209. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414020926223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reuter, OJ and Gandhi, J (2011) Economic Performance and Elite Defection from Hegemonic Parties. British Journal of Political Science 41(1), 83110. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123410000293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reuter, OJ and Szakonyi, D (2019) Elite Defection under Autocracy: Evidence from Russia. American Political Science Review 113(2), 552568. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055419000030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rijkers, B, Arouri, H and Baghdadi, L (2017) Are Politically Connected Firms More Likely to Evade Taxes? Evidence from Tunisia. World Bank Economic Review 30, 166175. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhw018.Google Scholar
Rithmire, M (2023) Precarious Ties: Business and the State in Authoritarian Asia. New York: Oxford University Press.10.1093/oso/9780197697528.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, S (2022) How Viktor Orbán Is Squeezing Foreign Supermarkets Out of Hungary. Politico, 10 November.Google Scholar
Schmidt-Catran, AW and Fairbrother, M (2016) The Random Effects in Multilevel Models: Getting Them Wrong and Getting Them Right. European Sociological Review 32(1), 2338. https://doi.org/10.1093/esr/jcv090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sebők, M and Simons, J (2022) How Orbán Won? Neoliberal Disenchantment and the Grand Strategy of Financial Nationalism to Reconstruct Capitalism and Regain Autonomy. Socio-Economic Review 20(4), 16251651. https://doi.org/10.1093/ser/mwab052.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shih, VC (ed.) (2020) Economic Shocks and Authoritarian Stability: Duration, Financial Control, and Institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.10.3998/mpub.11354716CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sinanoglu, S (2023) Taming a Paper Tiger? A Political Economy of Support for the Repression of the Business Elite. Preprint. https://osf.io/zqcyt_v1/.10.31219/osf.io/zqcytCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sinanoglu, S (2024) The Cost of Co-optation: Tax Audit as Authoritarian Financial Repression during Debt Crises. Preprint. www.researchgate.net/publication/392093558_The_Cost_of_Co-optation_Tax_Audit_as_Authoritarian_Financial_Repression.Google Scholar
Sinanoglu, S, Way, L and Levitsky, S (2025) Can Capitalism Save Democracy? Journal of Democracy 36(3), 515. https://doi.org/10.1353/jod.2025.a964562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svolik, MW (2012) The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9781139176040CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szakonyi, D (2020) Politics for Profit: Business, Elections, and Policymaking in Russia. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/9781108869089CrossRefGoogle Scholar
T24 (2020) Mahkeme Tarafından Imar Planı Iptal Edilen Buyukyalı Projesi Icin Bakanlıktan Yeni Adım. 4 January.Google Scholar
Wilson, MC and Wright, J (2017) Autocratic Legislatures and Expropriation Risk. British Journal of Political Science 47(1), 117. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123415000149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, SH (2015) Real Estate Elite, Economic Development, and Political Conflicts in Postcolonial Hong Kong. China Review 15(1), 138. www.jstor.org/stable/24291927.Google Scholar
Wright, J (2008) Do Authoritarian Institutions Constrain? How Legislatures Affect Economic Growth and Investment. American Journal of Political Science 52(2), 322343. www.jstor.org/stable/25193816.10.1111/j.1540-5907.2008.00315.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, J (2020) The Role of Corporate Political Connections in Commercial Lawsuits: Evidence from Chinese Courts. Comparative Political Studies 53(14), 23212358. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414020919962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, C (2021) Governing and Ruling: The Political Logic of Taxation in China. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.10.3998/mpub.11945851CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, J and Zhang, D (2017) Weapons of the Powerful: Authoritarian Elite Competition and Politicized Anticorruption in China. Comparative Political Studies 50(9), 11861220. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414016672234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Game Tree

Figure 1

Figure 2. The Exponentiated Coefficients from the Main GLM PL-FE Models for Business Support and Opposition

Notes: Co-optation Is operationalized with executive corrupt exchanges. All models include a lagged dependent variable (DV). Full regression tables are reported in Table C1 in the Supplementary Material.
Figure 2

Figure 3. The Average Marginal Effect of Co-optation on Business Support and Opposition

Notes: Co-optation is operationalized with executive corrupt exchanges.
Figure 3

Figure 4. Posterior Distributions of Effect Size with 95% Credible Intervals, Bayesian Causal Mediation Analysis with Weakly Informative Priors

Supplementary material: File

Sinanoglu supplementary material

Sinanoglu supplementary material
Download Sinanoglu supplementary material(File)
File 9.5 MB