Hostname: page-component-54dcc4c588-mz6gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-09-14T14:39:49.522Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

To Oppose or Not to Oppose? Strategies of Opposition Parties’ Parliamentary Support for Government Legislation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2025

Rick L. van Well*
Affiliation:
Institute of Political Science, Leiden University, Leiden, The Netherlands
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

While opposition parties are expected to challenge the government and present alternatives, they often support government legislation. Synthesizing key theoretical explanations, this study examines how opposition parties weigh their goals of winning the next elections, joining or replacing the government and influencing policy. It is hypothesized that opposition parties are more likely to oppose bills when they see chances for boosting their electoral prospects or an early government alternation. Conversely, they support bills when they see chances for future coalition cooperation or policy influence. The analyses of parliamentary votes across four established democracies – Canada, Denmark, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom – over 75 years, show that opposition parties strategically prioritize these goals based on bill-specific factors and the institutional context. Most innovatively, office-seeking opposition parties’ strategic behaviour depends on the patterns of government alternation. These findings offer crucial insights into the complex trade-offs opposition parties navigate in parliament.

Information

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Government and Opposition Ltd.

The existence of parliamentary opposition is widely considered ‘very nearly the most distinctive characteristic of democracy itself’ (Dahl Reference Dahl and In Dahl1966b: xviii). Governments experience opposition from various actors within and outside parliament (e.g. interest groups, social movements, media and the judiciary). By continually scrutinizing and criticizing government actions, these actors make it harder for the government to abuse its executive power. Consequently, all forms of political opposition strengthen checks and balances within the political system. Only parliamentary opposition parties, however, provide a second crucial democratic good: they offer voters alternative policies and an alternative government (Andeweg Reference Andeweg, In Müller and Narud2013). If voters are dissatisfied with the incumbent government and its policies, they can vote for an alternative. Opposition parties are, therefore, not only an essential ingredient of liberal democracy but also play a crucial role in representative democracy’s electoral competition.

Although a modest body of literature on the relations between the parliamentary opposition and the government has emerged in recent years (Helms Reference Helms2023), the behaviour of opposition parties in parliament has remained understudied given its importance for representative democracy. Government–opposition relations are constituted by both adversarial and cooperative opposition party behaviour, although the relative importance of either opposition type may vary (King Reference King1976). In majoritarian systems, opposition parties typically behave more adversarially than in consensus democracies. Consensus democracies provide potential veto power and ‘co-governing devices’ to opposition parties (Helms Reference Helms2004). The institutional opportunity structures that shape government–opposition relations have been summarized in an ‘opposition power index’ (Garritzmann Reference Garritzmann2017) and a ‘policy-making power index of opposition players’ (Wegmann Reference Wegmann2022). Opposition parties use parliamentary institutions not only to fulfil their opposition or parliamentary functions (Louwerse and Otjes Reference Louwerse and Otjes2019; Otjes and Louwerse Reference Otjes and Louwerse2021); they also use them more strategically to weaken the government (Whitaker and Martin Reference Whitaker and Martin2022).

A prominent type of opposition behaviour is how opposition parties vote on government bills in parliament. This behaviour ‘has strong symbolic power, as it clearly expresses conflict or consensus, in other words, agreement or rejection of how the government carries out its job’ (De Giorgi and Ilonszki Reference De Giorgi, Ilonszki, In De Giorgi and Ilonszki2018a: 241). Rather than oppose, opposition parties often support the government (De Giorgi and Ilonszki Reference De Giorgi and Ilonszki2018b). This raises the question: under which circumstances do opposition parties choose to support or oppose government legislation?

The emerging literature on the parliamentary opposition has identified several factors that shape government–opposition relations. The ideological composition of the government and the ideological positions of opposition parties affect the level of agreement between government and opposition parties in parliamentary votes (De Giorgi and Marangoni Reference De Giorgi and Marangoni2015; Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020; Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017). Opposition parties may also be more willing to support government bills after receiving policy concessions from the government; opposition parties tend to be accommodated by governments when these governments lack majority support in parliament (Christiansen and Damgaard Reference Christiansen and Damgaard2008; Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020; Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017; Otjes and Louwerse Reference Otjes and Louwerse2024).

Other features also play a role in opposition behaviour. Larger opposition parties and opposition parties with prior government experience are generally more oppositional, arguably because these aspects increase opposition parties’ chances of alternating with the incumbent government, as suggested by a study of 16 parliaments (Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018). The longer an opposition party has been represented in parliament, the more supportive of the government it is, at least in the German Bundestag (Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020). Independent of party characteristics, opposition behaviour differs over the electoral cycle. In Sweden, for instance, opposition parties are less likely to support minority governments at the beginning and the end of the election cycle (Müller and König Reference Müller and König2021).

These studies have given insight into the degree of government–opposition divisions in parliamentary votes (Giuliani Reference Giuliani2008; Hix and Noury Reference Hix and Noury2016; Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017) and differences in terms of parliamentary behaviour across opposition parties (De Giorgi and Ilonszki Reference De Giorgi and Ilonszki2018b; De Giorgi and Marangoni Reference De Giorgi and Marangoni2015; Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020; Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018). How the topic of the vote at hand affects the voting behaviour of opposition parties has remained relatively unexplored (Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020; Mújica and Sánchez‐Cuenca Reference Mújica and Sánchez‐Cuenca2006; Müller Reference Müller2024). Recent work also often lacks an explicit and unified theoretical framework of opposition behaviour. Consequently, we still lack systematically empirically tested explanations of opposition voting behaviour across countries, governments, parties and bills in established parliamentary democracies.

Aiming to understand opposition party behaviour further, this article takes a holistic approach, bringing various theoretical explanations together in a single framework, building on (implicit) arguments from previous studies. Building on the work of Kaare Strøm and Wolfgang Müller (Reference Strøm, Müller, In Müller and Strøm1999), I propose that opposition parties’ decisions to support or oppose government legislation are based on their strategies to leave or exploit their position in the opposition. Depending on the issue that is being voted on, opposition parties may oppose the government to build their distinctive profile or to stimulate an early government alternation; they may support the government to signal their willingness to cooperate in a future coalition government or receive policy concessions from the government in exchange.

The analyses focus not merely on structural differences between parties, but specifically on bill-specific features. To test the expectations, data are employed on parliamentary votes during the period 1945–2020 in four theoretically motivated country cases of established parliamentary democracies, including two-party systems (the United Kingdom and Canada) and multiparty systems (Denmark and the Netherlands), and countries with a tradition of minority governments (Canada and Denmark) and majority governments (the Netherlands and the United Kingdom). The findings indicate that a government bill’s policy area affects opposition parties’ voting decisions in parliament. These findings provide important insights into government–opposition relations that can help society monitor political representatives.

Opposition goals and government support

Various explanations of opposition behaviour can be brought together in a single theoretical framework using the classic policy/office/votes triad of party behaviour (Strøm Reference Strøm1990a; Strøm and Müller Reference Strøm, Müller, In Müller and Strøm1999). In this framework, opposition parties are expected to choose the course of action that they believe, under the present institutional constraints, will have the best consequences for their preferences. This framework distinguishes between three distinct preferences or goals that parties aim to achieve: maximum electoral support (votes), control of cabinet positions (office) and changing public policies (policy).

The first two goals are easily identified in the stereotypical image of government–opposition relations shaped by Prime Minister’s Questions in the British House of Commons. The leader of the opposition arguing strongly with the prime minister in parliament reflects the adage of 19th-century statesman Edward Stanley, the Earl of Derby, that ‘The Duty of an Opposition [is] very simple … to oppose everything, and propose nothing!’ The Westminster depiction of a parliamentary opposition is an opposition with barely any leverage against the government, besides ‘good reasons, and time’ (King Reference King1976: 18). In the short term, then, the opposition prioritizes votes over policy and office: it is a ‘government-in-waiting’ that can only aim to win the next elections to replace the incumbent government and obtain control over government policies (Hix and Noury Reference Hix and Noury2016; Laver Reference Laver, In Wittman and Weingast2006; Shugart Reference Shugart, Binder, Rhodes and Rockman2006). Though the relationship between electoral results, government participation and policy influence is less direct in multiparty systems, even here votes matter greatly to parties for them to influence policies or to increase the likelihood of coalition participation (Downs Reference Downs1957: 159).

Opposition behaviour in parliament influences electoral outcomes. Voters evaluate the performance of governing parties more negatively when government actions are criticized and opposed by opposition parties (Seeberg Reference Seeberg2020). Whereas voters can hold governing parties accountable for their performance in office, they can hold opposition parties accountable for their behaviour in parliament. Opposition parties are generally assumed to benefit electorally from criticizing and opposing the government. Opposition parties who cooperate structurally with minority governments are more disliked by voters who are dissatisfied with the government and they generally lose votes in the next elections (Hjermitslev Reference Hjermitslev2024; Thürk and Klüver Reference Thürk and Klüver2024). Although many voters detest unconstructive and disruptive opposition (Louwerse and Zorina Reference Louwerse and Zorina2025; Stiers Reference Stiers2023), opposition parties that vote more frequently against the government in parliament generally do better in the next elections than opposition parties that vote more frequently with the government (Tuttnauer and Wegmann Reference Tuttnauer and Wegmann2022; Williams Reference Williams2011). Opposing the government meets people’s expectations of a good opposition, and it may help opposition parties present themselves as an ideologically distinct alternative to the incumbent government. When voters see no differences between the government and the opposition, they will feel no need to replace the government with the opposition.

As long as voters do not notice parliamentary voting behaviour, opposition parties might get away with supporting the government. To explain opposition parties’ behaviour, however, it matters to what degree parties think that their votes in parliament shape the public’s perception of them. Voting on government bills is one of the most important and visible activities in parliament. Considering that parliamentary behaviour shapes media narratives about interparty conflicts (Fortunato Reference Fortunato2021) and parties often advertise their and each other’s voting decisions on social media and press releases (Tuttnauer and Wegmann Reference Tuttnauer and Wegmann2022), it is easy to understand how opposition parties vote strategically to appeal to voters (Louwerse and Otjes Reference Louwerse and Otjes2019; Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018).

Voting against the government’s legislation can be particularly attractive as it is considered a ‘mediatized signalling tool for opposition parties as an explicit and clearly attributable expression of party positions and their attitude toward the government’ (Tuttnauer and Wegmann Reference Tuttnauer and Wegmann2022: 1357). Here, opposition parties have a strategic advantage in deciding their position, because they ‘usually do not have to commit themselves on any issue until after … the government has revealed its policy’ and then they ‘can select the optimum strategy to counteract it’ (Downs Reference Downs1957: 52). By opposing the government’s position, opposition parties send signals to voters who are unsatisfied with the incumbent government (Ganghof and Bräuninger Reference Ganghof and Bräuninger2006; Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018) (see Table 1).

Table 1. The Goals of Opposition Parties and Corresponding Behaviour in Parliament

Next to the desire to win elections, office aspirations can also influence opposition parties’ relations with the government. Here, seeking office means aiming to maximize a party’s share of cabinet positions. Opposition parties may pursue office because of the intrinsic value of having ministerial posts – ‘income, prestige, and power’ (Downs Reference Downs1957: 28) – or for its instrumental value: to influence public policies ‘it is almost always better to be in office than not’ (Strøm and Müller Reference Strøm, Müller, In Müller and Strøm1999: 6). Regardless of the reason for pursuing office, office-seeking means wanting to leave the opposition and become or join the government. Office-seeking motivations may lead opposition parties to oppose the government if that helps them to foster a government defeat in parliament or stimulate conflicts within the government, resulting in early elections or a government alternation. On the other hand, they may also lead opposition parties to support the government to signal trustworthiness and responsibility as potential partners for a future coalition government (Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017). The best strategy for opposition parties to leave the opposition depends on how credible they can make a claim to replace the incumbent government after the next elections (Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018).

For opposition parties, vote-seeking and office-seeking behaviour are investments for the future – that is, the next government formation or the next elections. However, parties do not necessarily have to wait until it is their turn to govern to ‘maximize [their] impact on public policy’ in the short term (Strøm and Müller Reference Strøm, Müller, In Müller and Strøm1999: 7, emphasis added). Although policy-seeking behaviour is more associated with the government and government legislation, ‘even opposition parties can enjoy some policy influence in most parliamentary democracies’ and, therefore, the ‘role of the opposition is not simply to criticize and present an alternative government’ (Strøm Reference Strøm1990b: 42). Here, opposition parties can try to accomplish some policy goals, not only by introducing private members’ bills but also by shaping the parliamentary agenda, cooperating with policy specialists from the government parties and introducing amendments. The policy influence differential varies across parliaments (Garritzmann Reference Garritzmann2017; Helms Reference Helms2004; Powell Reference Powell2000; Strøm Reference Strøm1990b: 42; Wegmann Reference Wegmann2022). Still, rather than aiming to leave the opposition, the opposition in any parliament can opt to exploit its position to aim for policy gains (Ilonszki and De Giorgi Reference Ilonszki, De Giorgi, De Giorgi and Ilonszki2018: 5).

Initiating most legislation, the government remains the central policymaking body in most political systems. Instead of distinguishing themselves from the government, opposition parties may opt to cooperate with the government to change public policies in a more favourable direction. During the legislative review process, they can influence policies, particularly when parliamentary committees enable them to monitor and control government policymaking (Fortunato Reference Fortunato2019; König et al. Reference König, Lin and Silva2023; Strøm Reference Strøm1990b). Opposition parties may also negotiate policy concessions in exchange for their support (Anghel and Thürk Reference Anghel and Thürk2021; Christiansen and Seeberg Reference Christiansen and Seeberg2016; Otjes and Louwerse Reference Otjes and Louwerse2024).

Even when governments do not need the numerical support of opposition parties, the wishes of opposition parties are sometimes still accommodated by the government to ‘silence’ opposition criticism (Green-Pedersen and Mortensen Reference Green-Pedersen and Mortensen2010; Seeberg Reference Seeberg2013, Reference Seeberg2023; Thesen Reference Thesen2013). Although opposition parties may strongly attack and criticize the government to put new issues on the political agenda, opposition parties will ultimately support government bills that accommodate their wishes. Typically this adversarial rhetorical behaviour is also motivated by opposition parties’ efforts to ‘influence elections and voters’ evaluations of the government’ rather than efforts to change the government’s policy, even though this behaviour ‘may have policy implications because the government legislates to silence opposition agenda-setting’ (Seeberg Reference Seeberg2023: 466). Therefore, policy-seeking motivations may generally lead opposition parties to support the government, either because the government’s legislation is closer to opposition parties’ policy preferences than the status quo or because the government accommodates the wishes of opposition parties in exchange for support.

Opposition goals trade-offs and expectations

Even though winning elections, becoming the government and exerting policy influence are clearly interrelated objectives, it should be clear by now that also for parties in the opposition ‘[t]he same behaviour that maximizes one [objective] may not lead to the best possible outcome with respect to the others’ (Strøm and Müller Reference Strøm, Müller, In Müller and Strøm1999: 9). Depending on their ‘time horizons’, parties prioritize a certain goal over others, at least in the short term. Because parties in the opposition engage in different strategic behaviours to achieve office, policy and votes (Ilonszki and De Giorgi Reference Ilonszki, De Giorgi, De Giorgi and Ilonszki2018), making an analytical distinction between these three goals helps understand why opposition parties support or oppose the government.

Depending on the (institutional) context, opposition parties face different trade-offs between their goals, and they will exhibit different strategic behaviours in parliament. One important trade-off exists between policy-seeking and vote-seeking opposition behaviour (Andeweg Reference Andeweg, In Müller and Narud2013). Voters may become dissatisfied with opposition parties who continually support or work together with the government. Julian Garritzmann (Reference Garritzmann2017: 8) describes the tension between opposition roles: ‘political actors seeking to remain credible cannot shape policy-making and simultaneously criticize and present distinct alternatives to results that they themselves have shaped; other political actors would highlight the opposition’s inconsistent behaviour.’

A crucial factor that shapes the way opposition parties weigh policy-seeking and vote-seeking behaviour against each other is their policy positions (De Giorgi and Marangoni Reference De Giorgi and Marangoni2015; Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020). It is very unattractive for an opposition party to support government policies when there is a large difference between the party’s and the government’s policy positions. Even if an opposition party manages to receive some policy concessions from the government, it is highly unlikely that the result will leave their voters satisfied in that case (Ganghof and Bräuninger Reference Ganghof and Bräuninger2006). If an opposition party’s position on a particular issue is close to the government’s, that opposition party may find it easier to support the government: the party may consider the government’s policy an improvement over the status quo or it may be easier to compromise with the government over such an issue without giving too much away. This will leave voters more satisfied than if opposition parties should support government policies that are further away from the party’s ideal point. For governing parties too, it is more attractive to seek cooperation with and accommodate ideologically close opposition parties than with ideologically distant opposition parties (Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017):

Policy distance hypothesis: The larger the distance is between an opposition party’s policy position and the government’s policy position in a policy area, the less likely it is that the opposition party will support government bills in that policy area.

The trade-off between policy-seeking and vote-seeking behaviour may also tilt further in favour of policy-seeking when the opposition possesses veto power over legislation – for example under minority governments. Substantive minority governments must build ad hoc majority support for every proposal in order to survive and implement its policies (Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017; Strøm, 1990). Opposition parties may allow the survival of minority governments in order to obtain substantial policy gains (Artés and Bustos Reference Artés and Bustos2008). This only holds for ‘genuine’ minority governments, though. There are important differences between minority governments working on an issue-by-issue basis with different opposition parties (substantial minority governments) and those with long-term partnerships with formal support parties (Strøm Reference Strøm1990b; Thürk and Klüver Reference Thürk and Klüver2024). The latter case differs only a little from the situation of a majority government. These formal minority governments have secured majority support for their main policies and confidence votes and are ‘majority governments in disguise’ (Strøm Reference Strøm1990b: 61), evidenced by similar levels of legislative performance and survival rates to majority governments (Krauss and Thürk Reference Krauss and Thürk2022; Thürk Reference Thürk2022).

Under substantive minority governments, opposition parties are in a stronger position to change policies or prevent undesirable changes. These minority governments will try to accommodate opposition parties to safeguard majority support in parliament for their legislation. They negotiate support from opposition parties before or during the legislative review process (Christiansen and Damgaard Reference Christiansen and Damgaard2008; Christiansen and Pedersen Reference Christiansen and Pedersen2014). This means there are more incentives for opposition parties to opt for policy-seeking behaviour when making a trade-off between policy and votes. Consequently, opposition parties will be more likely to vote in favour of those government bills.

Additionally, the role of opposition parties’ policy preferences may be stronger under a substantive minority government than under a majority government. Under majority governments, opposition parties have stronger incentives to oppose the government even if they prefer government legislation over the status quo (Dewan and Spirling Reference Dewan and Spirling2011). Under substantive minority governments, opposition parties can tilt the support for a government bill to a majority. Thus, under minority governments, support for the government will be affected more by parties’ ‘policy positions rather than by government–opposition splits’ (Hix and Noury Reference Hix and Noury2016: 254; Klüver and Zubek Reference Klüver and Zubek2018).

Minority government hypothesis: Under substantive minority governments, opposition parties are more likely to support government bills than under majority governments or formal minority governments.

Minority government–policy distance hypothesis: Under substantive minority governments, the effect of policy distance on opposition parties’ support for government bills is stronger than under majority governments or formal minority governments.

Opposing the government to win votes at the next election can come with a trade-off of forgoing any possible policy influence while being in opposition and at a lower chance of joining a future coalition government with one of the incumbent governing parties. Opposition parties are expected to prioritize vote-seeking behaviour in situations where that behaviour will be most effective: when opposition parties feel more strongly monitored by voters, they will feel incentivized to do things that will benefit them electorally. When opposition parties ‘do their work away from the centers of public attention’ they are more inclined to cooperate with the government as ‘opportunities are more available and compromises less embarrassing’ (Strøm Reference Strøm1990b: 43).

Opposition parties should be expected to be monitored most closely by the electorate on their core issues. Their behaviour in their most important policy areas is more important for preserving a party profile distinct from the government (Budge Reference Budge2015). On salient issues on which they have very different preferences from the government, opposition parties should be particularly oppositional. Opposing the government is probably not equally beneficial electorally for all parties in all contexts. When opposition parties are close to the government on issues that are important to them, they may be more willing to support the government. It is harder for opposition parties to credibly oppose government legislation that is congruent with (or very close to) their policy preferences. This is especially true in multiparty systems in which opposition parties have to position themselves vis-à-vis other parties in the opposition in addition to the government (Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020). Opposing the government in that situation is not only less credible, but gaining policy influence may be more likely and less costly because it is easier for parties to justify their support for the government and be rewarded for it by their voters (Müller Reference Müller2024; Thesen et al. Reference Thesen, Green-Pedersen and Mortensen2017).

Issue saliency–policy distance hypothesis: The more salient a policy area is to an opposition party, the stronger the effect of policy distance on its support for government bills in that policy area.

Office-seeking motivations may lead opposition parties to oppose the government if that helps them advance an early government alternation. The threat of a parliamentary defeat may unite the governing party or parties in their support of the government and incentivize the opposition to vote collectively against the government (Hix and Noury Reference Hix and Noury2016: 252). Although most governments terminate early rather than serving their full term, they rarely terminate because of a defeat in parliament by the opposition. For coalition governments, the most frequent reason for early termination is a policy conflict between the coalition partners (Damgaard Reference Damgaard, Strøm, Müller and Bergman2008).

Bridging diverging policy preferences through compromise can be very painful for coalition parties. The constitutional doctrine of collective cabinet responsibility can be a risk for coalition parties. According to this doctrine, all members of the government should support all government actions. As a consequence, coalition parties in parliament generally vote in the same way on government legislation, even if they have very diverging policy preferences (Laver Reference Laver, In Wittman and Weingast2006: 137). They will not allow their partners to vote against the government compromise. Coalition unity may hurt them electorally because voters may feel that their party is giving too much away (Hjermitslev Reference Hjermitslev2020; Klüver and Spoon Reference Klüver and Spoon2020). For coalition parties, collective cabinet responsibility is ‘an electoral straitjacket, effectively eliminating a cabinet member’s potential to defend themselves’ (Fortunato Reference Fortunato2021: 94).

Opposition parties that want to leave the opposition or prefer a different government can exploit coalition parties’ electoral vulnerability by increasing intra-coalition tensions. An effective way to do this is to expose and highlight disagreements or ‘policy wedges’ between the governing parties (Van de Wardt et al. Reference Van de Wardt, De Vries and Hobolt2014). Exposing policy differences and compromises among coalition parties can destabilize a coalition government (Laver Reference Laver, In Wittman and Weingast2006: 130). It embarrasses coalition parties and communicates to voters that coalition parties have given away too much to their partners (Fortunato Reference Fortunato2021). This will hurt coalition parties electorally at the next elections, and it may result in increasing tensions among coalition parties and in the early termination of the government (So Reference So2024).

One way to ‘divide to conquer’ the government is by asking parliamentary questions on policy issues on which the governing parties’ policy preferences diverge (Whitaker and Martin Reference Whitaker and Martin2022). Another way of publicizing these policy wedges is voting against government bills that concern policy domains on which coalition parties diverge ideologically. A situation in which a governing party tilts the vote to a majority for unpopular policies may be especially painful for it. This strategy may not only hurt the stability and prospects of government duration but also hurt the governing parties’ reputations and electoral prospects at the next election.

Coalition issue divisiveness hypothesis: The more governing parties’ policy positions in a policy area diverge, the less likely it is that opposition parties support a government bill in that policy area.

The prospects of a party that uses an adversarial opposition style entering the next government depends on the governing potential of opposition parties and the government alternation patterns in a political system. Governmental potential refers to opposition parties’ aspirations for office and the likelihood of getting involved in government formation and is often operationalized as whether that party has had prior government experience (Sartori Reference Sartori1976; Schumacher et al. Reference Schumacher2015; Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018). Opposition parties with none or only little governing potential will probably put a stronger weight on policy-seeking or vote-seeking motivations than on office-seeking motivations. The strategy for potential governing parties to win office depends on the structure of party competition (Mair Reference Mair, LeDuc and Niemi1996; Otjes Reference Otjes2020).

In systems of wholesale alternation, two parties or two blocs of parties alternate in government. The route to government for office-seeking opposition parties in these systems is to win a majority (or plurality) of seats (or for their bloc) at the next election. In these systems, early elections and being distinct from the government are the most rational routes to becoming the government in the long term. Attacking the government, then, is a requirement to offer a credible alternative government to the electorate (Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018).Footnote 1 For these opposition parties, ‘the basic conviction … prevails, “that it is better to give the government enough rope to hang itself with” than demonstrating its fitness for office and trying to win the voters’ trust by helping the government to govern’ (Helms Reference Helms2008: 15). For opposition parties without governing potential, campaigning against the government is not a self-evident strategy. As they are unlikely to gain government participation through winning votes, their only way to influence policies is by exploiting the parliamentary opportunities to influence public policies. To do that, they need to act more cooperatively towards the government (Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018).

Contrarily, in systems of partial alternation, parties that are separated into government and opposition camps at one time may form a coalition government together at another time. Elections in these systems – however important – are less deterministic for government formation. Here, office-seeking opposition parties risk being excluded from future coalitions when they act too antagonistically towards the government (Ganghof and Bräuninger Reference Ganghof and Bräuninger2006; Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017; Tavits Reference Tavits2008). Therefore, they will moderate their attitude towards the government or even actively seek cooperation, signalling trust and gaining a reputation as future coalition partners (Bale and Bergman Reference Bale and Bergman2006). Cooperative behaviour may affect parties’ reputation positively as reliable partners in future coalition governments. Compared to permanent opposition parties, engaging in ‘divide to conquer’ strategies could hurt opposition parties with governing potential in systems of partial alternation because this ‘could risk imperilling relationships with past and prospective coalition partners’ (Van de Wardt et al. Reference Van de Wardt, De Vries and Hobolt2014: 987).

Governing potential hypothesis: In systems of wholesale alternation (Canada, Denmark, the United Kingdom), the more governing potential an opposition party has, the less likely it is to support government bills. In systems of partial alternation (the Netherlands), the more governing potential an opposition party has, the more likely it is to support government bills.

Governing potential–coalition issue divisiveness hypothesis: In systems of wholesale alternation (Denmark), the more governing potential an opposition party has, the stronger the effect of coalition issue divisiveness is on support for government bills. In systems of partial alternation (the Netherlands), the more governing potential an opposition party has, the weaker the effect of coalition issue divisiveness is on support for government bills.

Methods and data

The analyses include parliamentary votes in four established parliamentary democracies: Canada, Denmark, the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. These countries were selected to maximize institutional variation and increase the findings’ generalizability. To inform the country case selection, two institutional features known to affect government–opposition distinctiveness were considered. First, the difference between two-party systems (the United Kingdom and Canada) and multiparty systems (the Netherlands and Denmark) represents differences in the competition between political parties (Lijphart Reference Lijphart2012). The second feature that informed the country case selection is the occurrence of minority governments. Denmark has the largest share of minority governments of all established parliamentary democracies: roughly 90% of Danish governments since 1945 had a minority status. Compared to Denmark, Canada has had far fewer minority governments, but for a majoritarian democracy, a third of the governments having had a minority status is still quite substantial. In the United Kingdom and the Netherlands, majority governments have been the norm. This diverse set of country cases contributes to the generalizability of the findings.

Additionally, the selected countries differ in their patterns of government alternation (Otjes Reference Otjes2020). In the United Kingdom, the Conservative Party and the Labour Party have alternated in mostly single-party government. In Canada, the Liberal Party and the Conservative Party have competed over single-party governments. Despite the Danish parliament’s high levels of fragmentation, the party system can be divided into a left bloc (Social Democrats and Social Liberals) and a right bloc (Liberals and the Conservative People’s Party) that usually alternate in single-party or coalition government. Deviating from these patterns of wholesale alternation, the Dutch fragmented party systems have led to the formation of coalition governments including at least one party that had previously been in government. In the Netherlands, there has never been an instance of wholesale alternation and, until the formation of the 2024 government, every government had included at least two of the three traditional parties: the Christian Democrats (or its predecessors), the Liberals and the Labour Party.

This study focuses on the decision of opposition parties to support or oppose government legislation. Whereas earlier research focused on the differences in government support between opposition parties (De Giorgi and Marangoni Reference De Giorgi and Marangoni2015; Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018) or on differences in the government–opposition distinction between parliamentary votes (Giuliani Reference Giuliani2008; Louwerse et al. Reference Louwerse2017), this analysis focused on the individual voting decisions of opposition parties, enabling the estimation of the impact of party- and bill-specific features on opposition behaviour (cf. Müller Reference Müller2024).

The unit of analysis is an opposition party’s voting decision on a government bill (in favour or against). Data on the voting behaviour in parliament of opposition parties were taken from Tom Louwerse and Rick van Well (Reference Louwerse and van Well2023), who assembled parliamentary voting data from various country-specific sources. This dataset spans an extensive period, from approximately 1945 to 2020 in all four parliaments. From this dataset, all voting decisions of opposition parties on government bills from non-caretaker governments were selected. Abstentions and parliamentary votes in which governing parties voted against the bill were excluded. The data on votes in the British House of Commons did not allow a distinction between government and private members’ bills and therefore all bills that the government party voted in favour of were included. Most of these will be government bills as it is rare for votes to take place on private members’ bills. Finally, votes on bills with missing information on bill topics or party were excluded ultimately resulting in 76,243 voting decisions on 14,148 government bills made by 351 opposition parties in 83 cabinet terms in 4 countries (see Table 2).

Table 2. Overview of Empirical Observations

The dependent variable in this study is the opposition parties’ support for government bills. Opposition parties’ support for government legislation was captured in a simple dichotomous measure: whether the majority of a party voted in support of (1) or in opposition to (0) the government bill. It must be noted that the meaning of an opposition party’s voting decision may differ slightly across parliaments, depending on the voting procedure. In the Danish Folketing, all government bills get a vote, whereas in the British House of Commons probably only the most politically salient bills get to a vote because of the cumbersome voting procedure (‘division’) (Hug Reference Hug, In Narud and Müller2013). Since the number of bills is quite different across parliaments, the degree of government–opposition distinctiveness cannot be truly compared between countries. Many of the bills voted on in the Netherlands and Denmark may be less controversial than the typical bill voted on in the United Kingdom or Canada. For the analyses conducted here, the limitations of this operationalization are not too problematic, though, as they focus mainly on explaining within-country variation. Furthermore, a study of voting in the German parliament found that ‘opposition behavior does not differ systematically between recorded and nonrecorded votes suggesting that parties act consistently across all votes’ (Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Sieberer and Wenzig2024). The sample of bills that were voted on in parliament is therefore likely to be a valid measure for studying opposition behaviour in parliament.

For the operationalization of policy distance, issue saliency and coalition issue divisiveness, information on the topic of the bill was required. This information was largely retrieved from the Comparative Agendas Project (CAP). This project classifies various policy activities, including bills, into a single, universal and consistent coding scheme (Baumgartner et al. Reference Baumgartner, Breunig and Grossman2019). The coding scheme includes 21 major topics and over 200 subtopics used to hand-code policy activities. The bill topics for Denmark (1953–2017), Canada (1960–2010) and the Netherlands (1980–2009) provided by these data resources were matched to the parliamentary voting data.Footnote 2 The Dutch data were extended to 2021 by a coder using the Dutch master codebook. Because the British voting data and CAP data did not share a similar unique identifier and the number of votes on British government bills was limited, these were also hand-coded using the British master codebook.

The policy preferences of political parties were measured using data from the Manifesto Research on Political Representation (MARPOR) dataset (previously known as the Comparative Manifestos Project (CMP)). MARPOR has collected and hand-coded election manifestos since 1945 in over 50 countries, including the four country cases in this study (Volkens et al. Reference Volkens2020). Sentences in parties’ election manifestos were sorted into one of 56 categories, resulting in percentages of each manifesto falling into each category. Rather than relying on the general left–right party positions that can be derived from these data, a more fine-grained measurement of party positions on specific policy dimensions was used; seven policy areas were constructed for which MARPOR categories were matched to CAP policy areas (see Appendix A in the Supplementary Material). For the estimation of issue-specific party, Will Lowe et al.’s (Reference Lowe2011) scaling method was used, taking the logged ratio of positive and negative statements in each category.

To estimate the policy distance between opposition parties and the government, the government’s position on each policy issue was calculated first. For single-party governments, the manifesto measures of the governing party were assumed to represent the government’s positions. The policy positions of coalition governments were operationalized as the seat-weighted average of the policy positions of the coalition parties, whereby formal support parties to minority governments were treated as coalition parties. The policy distances between parties and the government were calculated by taking the absolute distance between a party’s position and the government’s position. Coalition issue divisiveness was operationalized as the range – that is, the difference between the highest and lowest value – of coalition parties’ policy positions. For the estimation of issue saliency, Lowe et al.’s (Reference Lowe2011) method was used, taking the logged proportion of statements, whether positive or negative, in each category.

Information about cabinet type was derived from ParlGov (Döring and Manow Reference Döring and Manow2021). Formal support parties of minority governments were identified using Torbjörn Bergman et al.’s study (Reference Bergman, Bäck and Hellström2021). Minority governments that received majority support together with their formal support parties were classified as formal minority governments and other minority governments as substantive minority governments. Dummies for substantive minority government, as well as formal minority government and surplus majority government, were included in the analyses. As a proxy for governing potential, a continuous measure of government experience was used by dividing the number of days an opposition party had been in government by the total number of days this party had existed since 1918 (Schumacher et al. Reference Schumacher2015; Tuttnauer Reference Tuttnauer2018). As control variables, seat share (based on ParlGov), a formal support party dummy and policy area were included. See Appendix B in the Supplementary Material for descriptive statistics.

Findings

The data were structured in party–bill dyadics: voting decisions were nested into both opposition parties and bills, but parties and bills did not have a hierarchical structure. As the data were clustered within cabinet terms and bills they were analysed with multilevel logistic regression models, including random intercepts for cabinet and bill. Party-fixed effects (and effectively country-fixed effects) were also added to the model. The results of the pooled models are presented in Table 3.

Table 3. Multilevel Logistic Regression Analysis of Opposition Support for Government Bills

Notes: In all models, the number of observations is 76,243, the number of bills are 76,243, and the number of cabinets is 83. The reference category for cabinet type is minimal winning.

*** p < 0.001; ** p < 0.01; * p < 0.05; p < 0.1

The analyses offer empirical support for the policy distance hypothesis. The larger the differences between the positions of an opposition party and the government on a certain policy area, the lower the probability that the opposition party votes in favour of government bills in that area. This pattern of opposition behaviour was found across political systems and was statistically significant in all parliaments except for the Canadian House of Commons (see Appendix C, Table C1, in the Supplementary Material). On average, the probability of voting for a government bill decreases by 1.3 percentage points, with each standard deviation increase on the policy distance measure. This finding aligns with a ‘non-strategic’ spatial model of parliamentary voting behaviour in which opposition parties decide to support or oppose government bills based purely on the substantive content of the policies proposed (Hohendorf et al. Reference Hohendorf, Saalfeld, Sieberer, Bukow and Jun2020).

It also fits, however, the expectation that opposition parties make a trade-off between policy gains through government support and winning votes through opposing the government. When the positions of an opposition party and the government are too far apart, it is harder to credibly support the government. Supporting the government on policy issues on which an opposition party’s initial position is closer makes it easier to find compromises that are not too painful for opposition parties. Still, the size of the policy distance effect is modest, confirming again that spatial models of legislative behaviour are not sufficient to understand opposition behaviour in parliament adequately. To provide evidence for the main argument in this article that opposition parties act strategically, balancing their opposition goals, I now turn to the other findings.

Opposition support for the government was expected to increase under substantive minority governments. Substantive minority governments should be more willing to accommodate opposition parties in exchange for their much-needed support in parliament. For opposition parties in turn this should increase the benefits of policy-seeking behaviour and tilt the policy–vote trade-off further in favour of policy-seeking behaviour – that is, support of government bills. The probability of voting for government bills among opposition parties to substantive minority governments is 5.3 percentage points greater, on average, than the probability of voting for government bills among opposition parties to minimal winning governments. The differences between opposition behaviour under formal minority governments and minimal winning governments were not statistically significant, providing further evidence for the argument that formal minority governments are ‘majority governments in disguise’.

The role of policy distances to the government in opposition parties’ decision to support or oppose the government was also expected to increase under a substantive minority government. The results of the moderation analyses, however, show that the effect of policy distance only differs significantly between substantive minority governments and majority governments in Canada (Model 2). Here, policy distance only has a negative and significant effect under substantive minority governments in Canada but not under majority governments (see Appendix C, Table C2). In the other country models and the pooled model, however, there was no statistically significant moderation effect of cabinet type.

The trade-offs between the opposition objectives were expected to tilt further into vote-seeking behaviour when opposition parties feel more observed by voters. Under those circumstances, opposition parties’ voting behaviour should be informed more strongly by their policy positions, because the signal that their position in parliament sends to voters is more effective. When a party is positioned further away from the government, voting against the government comes with greater electoral benefits as it enables opposition parties to distinguish themselves from the government on their core issues. When positioned close to the government it is harder to oppose credibly and easier to justify support. The empirical analyses provide no support for these expectations (Model 3). Neither in the pooled model nor in the country models was the moderation effect of issue saliency and policy distance statistically significant. The main effect of issue saliency differs between countries. Only in the Dutch Tweede Kamer does issue saliency lead to a lower probability of voting in support of government bills (see Appendix C, Table C1). Contrarily, in Denmark and the United Kingdom, high issue saliency was associated with higher levels of support for government legislation.

Opposition parties should care not only about winning the next elections and exerting policy influence but also about replacing or joining the incumbent government. Increasing internal tensions within coalition governments could be a fruitful way to stimulate an early government alternation. Therefore, opposition parties were expected to oppose government bills on policy areas on which coalition parties were divided, in order to highlight the painful compromises coalition parties make and embarrass them. The analyses reveal support for this hypothesis only in the Dutch case. Here, for each standard deviation increase in the policy range within the government, the probability of voting in favour of government bills decreases by 1.4 percentage points. In Denmark, however, the coalition policy range did not have a significant effect (see Appendix C, Table C1).

The strategy of driving a wedge between coalition parties was hypothesized to be used to a different degree depending on the specific institutional context and the position of opposition parties within that context. First of all, office-seeking behaviour should be more attractive for those opposition parties that are likely to enter future governments than for parties that are or seem to be in opposition permanently. For those latter parties, policy and vote objectives should usually prevail. Second, the patterns of government alternation within a political system should determine the strategy employed by opposition parties with office aspirations. In systems of wholesale alternation, such as Canada, Denmark and the United Kingdom, attacking the incumbent government is the best way to stimulate government instability and a sooner replacement of the government. In systems of partial alternation, opposition parties should moderate their attitude towards the government to signal trust and responsibility towards future coalition partners who are currently in government. The analyses reveal that the more credible the position of the alternative government is for an opposition party, operationalized as the degree of government experience, the more the opposition parties will vote against government bills. This effect is only substantial and statistically significant in the systems of wholesale alternation and not in the country of partial alternation (the Netherlands).

Furthermore, moderation analyses of the Danish and Dutch cases show that Danish opposition parties aspiring for office use the wedge-driving strategy more, whereas their Dutch counterparts use the wedge-driving strategy less (see Table 4). This supports the expectation that the context of government alternation patterns affects the behaviour of opposition parties who aim to enter the government. In Denmark, the more government experience opposition parties have, the stronger the negative effect of coalition issue divisiveness is on support for government bills. In the Netherlands, the more government experience opposition parties have, the weaker the negative effect of coalition issue divisiveness is on support for government bills.

Table 4. Multilevel Logistic Regression Analyses of Opposition Support for Government Bills (With Government Experience and Government Policy Range Interaction)

Notes: The reference category for cabinet type is minimal winning.

*** p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05, p < 0.1.

Conclusion

For political parties, being in the opposition is hard. Opposition parties continually face difficult decisions about how they form their relationship with the government. They must position themselves strategically to offer voters coherent and contrasting sets of alternatives to choose from in the next elections. They must act strategically to stimulate an early government alternation while also increasing their chances of entering a future government. And they must leverage the power they have in parliament, though usually smaller than governing parties, to exert influence on public policies. This study has provided empirical evidence for the notion that opposition parties make trade-offs between these opposition goals depending on the issue at hand. Focusing especially on bill-specific features, it has systematically examined theoretically derived expectations centring on the dilemmas that opposition parties face daily between their objectives. The analyses leveraged extensive within-country variation in four theoretically motivated cases of established parliamentary democracies. The results largely provide empirical support for the idea that opposition parties’ decisions to support or oppose the government are motivated by policy-seeking, office-seeking and vote-seeking objectives and that opposition parties prioritize some of these motivations over others, depending on the government proposal at hand.

Whenever the circumstances allow for policy influence, opposition parties are inclined to support the government since they can exchange support for policy concessions from the government. This is the case when the policy preferences of opposition parties are close to the government’s and most effectively when the government is a ‘genuine’ minority government in dire need of opposition support. Legislation from minority governments that can rely on stable majority support because of formal agreements with one or more support parties is not as much supported by (genuine) opposition parties because formal minority governments have fewer incentives to accommodate the wishes of opposition parties. Contrary to expectations, the role of policy distances did not increase under substantive minority governments.

Even more fascinatingly, the present study has provided clear empirical evidence for the important role of the specific institutional context in which opposition parties compete for office. The employed cross-country data allowed for a comparative perspective on opposition behaviour across parliaments, making possible an estimation of the effect of governing potential and government issue divisiveness in different institutional contexts. As theoretically expected, the more government experience or office aspiration opposition parties have, the more their support for government bills is affected by a strategy to leave the opposition and enter the next government. This strategy depends on the prospects of the next government composition.

When opposition parties foresee replacing the incumbent government wholesale, as is the case in Denmark, Canada and the United Kingdom, office-seeking opposition parties are inclined to vote against the government – especially on bills in areas where the governing parties are divided – to stimulate tensions within the government and an early government alternation. On the other hand, when opposition parties foresee that they might cooperate with at least one of the incumbent governing parties in the next government, as is the case in the Netherlands, office-seeking opposition parties act more moderately to signal trust to future coalition partners. In these contexts, opposition parties with less experience and prospects of government participation are more inclined to vote against bills in areas where governing parties are divided.

As parliament is also a platform for national debate, it was theorized that opposition parties should vote more frequently against government legislation when that opposition could benefit them electorally. Although opposition parties are more likely to vote against government bills in areas where their policy preference diverge further from the government’s, opposition parties’ tendency to differentiate themselves from the government is not significantly higher in areas that are particularly salient to them. Possibly, opposition parties feel the need to act more responsibly on these issues. Cooperating with the government and exerting some policy influence on salient issues may actually help them present themselves as parties who can get things done. Alternatively, vote-seeking motivations may be less relevant for opposition parties in the parliamentary arena, at least in voting on government bills. Opposition parties may exploit different parliamentary tools to distinguish themselves from the government – for example in parliamentary debates or other parliamentary instruments – or they may use platforms outside of parliament to advertise their distinctive position, for example in the media. These are all leads for future studies.

Considering the contributions of this study, there still remains a wealth of questions about the relationship between government and opposition to be addressed. Whereas the present study focused on the impact of political and institutional circumstances on the trade-offs that opposition parties make between their goals, future work could aim to measure and explain the value that opposition parties attribute to each of their goals in general. Do opposition parties differ in the degree to which they intrinsically value the goal of winning votes, entering the government and exerting policy influence? There is also still much research to do on what the exact electoral and policy implications of opposition behaviour are. When do voters reward cooperative opposition behaviour, and does this differ across parties? Also, future research could take a government perspective on government–opposition relations: why do governments or governing parties support or oppose opposition proposals? Finally, a qualitative approach to government–opposition cooperation could investigate the drivers and causal mechanism of government–opposition distinctiveness more closely and tap more directly into what motivates the behaviour of opposition members of parliament.

For now, this study has emphasized that opposition parties face dilemmas on a daily basis, because they operate in both an electoral arena and a parliamentary arena. In the electoral arena, they experience incentives for competition, but in the parliamentary arena they often experience incentives for cooperation. There is some disagreement about the ideal relationship between the government and the opposition, but many scholars have warned against too much cooperation between government and opposition parties, as it risks the principles of concentrated responsibility and alternative government (Andeweg Reference Andeweg, In Müller and Narud2013; Dahl Reference Dahl and In Dahl1966a: 34; Kirchheimer Reference Kirchheimer1957: 136, 142). The question of how opposition parties deal with these tensions should continue to give rise to new advances in the study of the crucial relationship between government and opposition parties.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2025.8.

Acknowledgements

I thank Tom Louwerse, Petr Kopecký, Tim Mickler, Simon Otjes, Ulrich Sieberer, Maria Thürk, Simone Wegmann, Nikoleta Yordanova, the anonymous peer reviewers and the editors of Government and Opposition for comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this article. Kjell Boele and Rik Manuel provided invaluable research assistance. Jean-Philippe Gauvin shared the data from the Canadian Agendas Project with me. Gerard Breeman advised on how to extend the data from the Netherlands Agendas Project to 2021.

Financial support

This study is part of the project ‘Who Opposes?’ and was financially supported by a grant obtained by Tom Louwerse from the Dutch Research Council (NWO VI.Vidi.195.020).

Footnotes

1 Too adversarial an opposition style may hurt parties when they become the ones to be held accountable after government alternation: ‘an opposition party which knows that it may be called to “respond”, i.e. which is oriented towards governing and has a reasonable chance to govern or to have access to governmental responsibility, is likely to behave responsibly, in a restrained and realistic fashion. On the other hand, a “permanent opposition” which … knows it will not be called on to respond, Is likely to take the path of “irresponsible opposition”’ (Sartori Reference Sartori1966: 35, 152). This restraint, however, seems more relevant for the policy positions of opposition parties and opposition rhetoric than for votes on government bills.

2 The data in the Canadian Agendas Project have been collected by Stuart Soroka and Kelly Blidook (1968–2004) and Christine Rothmayr (1960–1968, 2004–2010). The data in the Danish Policy Agenda Project have been collected by Christoffer Green-Pedersen and Peter B. Mortensen with support from the Danish Social Science Research Council and the Research Foundation at Aarhus University. The data in the Netherlands Agendas Project have been collected by Arco Timmermans and Gerard Breeman with support from the Ministry of the Interior and Kingdom Relations at Leiden University.

References

Andeweg, RB (2013) Parties in Parliament: The Blurring of Opposition. In Müller, WC and Narud, HM (eds), Party Governance and Party Democracy. New York: Springer, pp. 99114.10.1007/978-1-4614-6588-1_6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anghel, V and Thürk, M (2021) Under the Influence: Pay-Offs to Legislative Support Parties under Minority Governments. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 56(1), 121140. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2019.11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Artés, J and Bustos, A (2008) Electoral Promises and Minority Governments: An Empirical Study. European Journal of Political Research 47(3), 307333. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2007.00722.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bale, T and Bergman, T (2006) Captives No Longer, but Servants Still? Contract Parliamentarism and the New Minority Governance in Sweden and New Zealand. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 41(3), 422449. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-7053.2006.00186.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumgartner, FR, Breunig, C and Grossman, E (eds) (2019) Comparative Policy Agendas: Theory, Tools, Data. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergman, T, Bäck, H and Hellström, J (eds) (2021) Coalition Governance in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/oso/9780198868484.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budge, I (2015) Issue Emphases, Saliency Theory and Issue Ownership: A Historical and Conceptual Analysis. West European Politics 38(4), 761777. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2015.1039374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, FJ and Damgaard, E (2008) Parliamentary Opposition under Minority Parliamentarism: Scandinavia. Journal of Legislative Studies 14(1–2), 4676. https://doi.org/10.1080/13572330801920937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, FJ and Pedersen, HH (2014) Minority Coalition Governance in Denmark. Party Politics 20(6), 940949. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068812462924.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, FJ and Seeberg, HB (2016) Cooperation between Counterparts in Parliament from an Agenda-Setting Perspective: Legislative Coalitions as a Trade of Criticism and Policy. West European Politics 39(6), 11601180. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2016.1157744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, RA (1966a) Epilogue. In Dahl, RA (ed.), Political Oppositions in Western Democracies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. pp. 387401.Google Scholar
Dahl, RA (1966b) Preface. In Dahl, RA (ed.), Political Oppositions in Western Democracies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, .Google Scholar
Damgaard, E (2008) Cabinet Termination. In Strøm, K, Müller, WC and Bergman, T (eds), Cabinets and Coaltion Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 301326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Giorgi, E and Ilonszki, G (2018a) Conclusions. In De Giorgi, E, and Ilonszki, G (eds), Opposition Parties in European Legislatures: Conflict or Consensus. London: Routledge. pp. 229246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Giorgi, E and Ilonszki, G (eds) (2018b) Opposition Parties in European Legislatures: Conflict or Consensus? London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Giorgi, E and Marangoni, F (2015) Government Laws and the Opposition Parties’ Behaviour in Parliament. Acta Politica 50(1), 6481. https://doi.org/10.1057/ap.2013.34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewan, T and Spirling, A (2011) Strategic Opposition and Government Cohesion in Westminster Democracies. American Political Science Review 105(2), 337358. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055411000050.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döring, H and Manow, P (2021) Parliaments and Governments Database (Parlgov): Information on Parties, Elections and Cabinets in Modern Democracies. Development Version. www.parlgov.org/ (Accessed: 22 July 2021).Google Scholar
Downs, A (1957) An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Fortunato, D (2019) Legislative Review and Party Differentiation in Coalition Governments. American Political Science Review 113(1), 242247. https://doi.org/10.1017/S000305541800062X.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fortunato, D (2021) The Cycle of Coalition: How Parties and Voters Interact under Coalition Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ganghof, S and Bräuninger, T (2006) Government Status and Legislative Behaviour: Partisan Veto Players in Australia, Denmark, Finland and Germany. Party Politics 12(4), 521539. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068806064732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garritzmann, JL (2017) How Much Power Do Oppositions Have? Comparing the Opportunity Structures of Parliamentary Oppositions in 21 Democracies. Journal of Legislative Studies 23(1), 130. https://doi.org/10.1080/13572334.2017.1283913.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giuliani, M (2008) Patterns of Consensual Law-Making in the Italian Parliament. South European Society and Politics 13(1), 6185. https://doi.org/10.1080/13608740802005777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green-Pedersen, C and Mortensen, PB (2010) Who Sets the Agenda and Who Responds to It in the Danish Parliament? A New Model of Issue Competition and Agenda-setting. European Journal of Political Research 49(2), 257281. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2009.01897.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helms, L (2004) Five Ways of Institutionalizing Political Opposition: Lessons from the Advanced Democracies. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 39(1), 2254. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0017-257x.2004.00030.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helms, L (2008) Studying Parliamentary Opposition in Old and New Democracies: Issues and Perspectives. Journal of Legislative Studies 14(1–2), 619. https://doi.org/10.1080/13572330801920788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helms, L (2023) Political Oppositions in Democratic and Authoritarian Regimes: A State-of-the-Field(s) Review. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 58(2), 391414. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2022.25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, S and Noury, A (2016) Government–Opposition or Left–Right? The Institutional Determinants of Voting in Legislatures. Political Science Research and Methods 4(2), 249273. https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2015.9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hjermitslev, IB (2020) The Electoral Cost of Coalition Participation: Can Anyone Escape? Party Politics 26(4), 510520. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068818794216.Google Scholar
Hjermitslev, IB (2024) Punishing the Pseudo-opposition: Accountability under a Minority Government. European Journal of Political Research 63(2), 774786. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12621.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hohendorf, L, Saalfeld, T and Sieberer, U (2020) Oppositional Strategies between Cooperation and Conflict: An Analysis of Opposition Party Voting in the German Bundestag, 1949–2013. In Bukow, S and Jun, U (eds), Continuity and Change of Party Democracies in Europe. Wiesbaden: Springer Vieweg, pp. 309342.10.1007/978-3-658-28988-1_11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hohendorf, L, Sieberer, U and Wenzig, J (2024) Recorded Votes as Attention Booster: How Opposition Parties Use Roll Calls and Nonrecorded Votes for Position Taking in the German Bundestag, 2017–21. Legislative Studies Quarterly 49(3), 649671. https://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hug, S (2013) Parliamentary Voting. In Narud, HM and Müller, WC (eds), Party Governance and Party Democracy. New York: Springer New York, pp. 137157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ilonszki, G and De Giorgi, E (2018) Introduction. In De Giorgi, E and Ilonszki, G (eds), Opposition Parties in European Legislatures: Conflict or Consensus? London and New York: Routledge, pp. 116.10.4324/9781315561011-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, A (1976) Modes of Executive-Legislative Relations: Great Britain, France, and West Germany. Legislative Studies Quarterly 1(1), 1136. https://doi.org/10.2307/439626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchheimer, O (1957) The Waning of Opposition in Parliamentary Regimes. Social Research 24(2), 127156.Google Scholar
Klüver, H and Spoon, J-J (2020) Helping or Hurting? How Governing as a Junior Coalition Partner Influences Electoral Outcomes. Journal of Politics 82(4), 12311242. https://doi.org/10.1086/708239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klüver, H and Zubek, R (2018) Minority Governments and Legislative Reliability: Evidence from Denmark and Sweden. Party Politics 24(6), 719730. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068817695742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
König, T, Lin, N and Silva, TN (2023) Government Dominance and the Role of Opposition in Parliamentary Democracies. European Journal of Political Research 62(2) 594611. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krauss, S and Thürk, M (2022) Stability of Minority Governments and the Role of Support Agreements. West European Politics 45(4), 767792. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2021.1890455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M (2006) Legislatures and Parliaments in Comparative Context. In Wittman, DA and Weingast, BR (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 121140.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A (2012) Patterns of Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Louwerse, T and Otjes, S (2019) How Populists Wage Opposition: Parliamentary Opposition Behaviour and Populism in the Netherlands. Political Studies 67(2), 479495. https://doi.org/10.1177/0032321718774717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Louwerse, T and van Well, RL (2023) Government–Opposition Distinctiveness in Legislatures: A Longitudinal Analysis. Paper presented at the Opposition Studies Conference, London, 18–19 July.Google Scholar
Louwerse, T and Zorina, E (2025) What Kind of Opposition Do Citizens Want? West European Politics, 125. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2025.2512288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Louwerse, T et al. (2017) Reaching across the Aisle: Explaining Government–Opposition Voting in Parliament. Party Politics 23(6), 746759. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068815626000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowe, W et al. (2011) Scaling Policy Preferences from Coded Political Texts. Legislative Studies Quarterly 36(1), 123155. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1939-9162.2010.00006.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mair, P (1996) Party Systems and Structures of Competition. In LeDuc, L and Niemi, RG (eds), Comparing Democracies: Elections and Voting in Global Perspective. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage, pp. 83106.Google Scholar
Mújica, A and Sánchez‐Cuenca, I (2006) Consensus and Parliamentary Opposition: The Case of Spain. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 41(1), 86108. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-7053.2006.00172.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, M (2024) Support Party Strategies on Important Policy Issues: Results from Swedish Minority Governments. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 59(1), 122. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, M and König, PD (2021) Timing in Opposition Party Support under Minority Government. Scandinavian Political Studies 44(2), 220243. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9477.12195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otjes, S (2020) How Fractionalisation and Polarisation Explain the Level of Government Turn-Over. Acta Politica 55(1), 4166. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41269-018-0098-9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otjes, S and Louwerse, T (2021) Do Anti-Elitist Parties Use Their Parliamentary Tools Differently? Parliamentary Affairs 74(3), 704721. https://doi.org/10.1093/pa/gsab027.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otjes, S and Louwerse, T (2024) The Reinvention of Consensus Politics: Governing without a Legislative Majority in the Netherlands 2010–2021. Acta Politica 59, 797821. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41269-023-00310-w.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, GB (2000) Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sartori, G (1966) Opposition and Control Problems and Prospects. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 1(2), 149154. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-7053.1966.tb00368.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, G (1976) Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schumacher, G et al. (2015) How Aspiration to Office Conditions the Impact of Government Participation on Party Platform Change. American Journal of Political Science 59(4), 10401054. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seeberg, HB (2013) The Opposition’s Policy Influence through Issue Politicisation. Journal of Public Policy 33(1), 89107. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0143814X12000190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seeberg, HB (2020) The Impact of Opposition Criticism on the Public’s Evaluation of Government Competence. Party Politics 26(4), 484495. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068818792578.Google Scholar
Seeberg, HB (2023) The Power of the Loser: Evidence on an Agenda-Setting Model of Opposition Policy Influence. European Journal of Political Research 62(2), 463485. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shugart, MS (2006) Comparative Executive–Legislative Relations. In Binder, SA, Rhodes, RAW and Rockman, BA (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 344365.Google Scholar
So, F (2024) Serious Conflicts with Benign Outcomes? the Electoral Consequences of Conflictual Cabinet Terminations. American Political Science Review 188(3), 14491463. https://doi.org/10.1017/S000305542300093X.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiers, D (2023) How Do Voters Evaluate Performance in Opposition? Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 58(4), 725744. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K (1990a) A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties on JSTOR. American Journal of Political Science 34(2), 565598. https://doi.org/10.2307/2111461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K (1990b) Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Strøm, K and Müller, WC (1999) Political Parties and Hard Choices. In Müller, WC and Strøm, K (eds), Policy, Office, or Votes? How Political Parties in Western Europe Make Hard Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 135.Google Scholar
Tavits, M (2008) The Role of Parties’ Past Behavior in Coalition Formation. American Political Science Review 102(4), 495507. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055408080362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thesen, G (2013) When Good News Is Scarce and Bad News Is Good: Government Responsibilities and Opposition Possibilities in Political Agenda-Setting. European Journal of Political Research 52(3), 364389. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2012.02075.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thesen, G, Green-Pedersen, C and Mortensen, PB (2017) Priming, Issue Ownership, and Party Support: The Electoral Gains of an Issue-Friendly Media Agenda. Political Communication 34(2), 282301. https://doi.org/10.1080/10584609.2016.1233920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thürk, M (2022) Small in Size but Powerful in Parliament? The Legislative Performance of Minority Governments. Legislative Studies Quarterly 47(1), 193224. https://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thürk, M and Klüver, H (2024) Hitting the Sweet Spot? The Electoral Consequences of Supporting Minority Governments. Comparative Political Studies 58, 16701698. https://doi.org/10.1177/00104140241271210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuttnauer, O (2018) If You Can Beat Them, Confront Them: Party-Level Analysis of Opposition Behavior in European National Parliaments. European Union Politics 19(2), 278298. https://doi.org/10.1177/1465116517752870.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuttnauer, O and Wegmann, S (2022) Voting for Votes: Opposition Parties’ Legislative Activity and Electoral Outcomes. American Political Science Review 116(4), 13571374. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055422000338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van de Wardt, M, De Vries, CE and Hobolt, SB (2014) Exploiting the Cracks: Wedge Issues in Multiparty Competition. Journal of Politics 76(4), 986999. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022381614000565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volkens, A et al. (2020) The Manifesto Data Collection. Manifesto Project (MRG/CMP/MARPOR). Version 2020b. Berlin: Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (WZB). https://doi.org/10.25522/MANIFESTO.MPDS.2020B.Google Scholar
Wegmann, S (2022) Policy-Making Power of Opposition Players: A Comparative Institutional Perspective. Journal of Legislative Studies 28(1), 125. https://doi.org/10.1080/13572334.2020.1843233.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Whitaker, R and Martin, S (2022) Divide to Conquer? Strategic Parliamentary Opposition and Coalition Government. Party Politics 28(6), 9991011. https://doi.org/10.1177/13540688211042859.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, LK (2011) Unsuccessful Success? Failed No-Confidence Motions, Competence Signals, and Electoral Support. Comparative Political Studies 44(11), 14741499. https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414011407470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. The Goals of Opposition Parties and Corresponding Behaviour in Parliament

Figure 1

Table 2. Overview of Empirical Observations

Figure 2

Table 3. Multilevel Logistic Regression Analysis of Opposition Support for Government Bills

Figure 3

Table 4. Multilevel Logistic Regression Analyses of Opposition Support for Government Bills (With Government Experience and Government Policy Range Interaction)

Supplementary material: File

van Well supplementary material

van Well supplementary material
Download van Well supplementary material(File)
File 46.5 KB