1. Introduction
Inequality is one of the most pressing challenges in contemporary societies, particularly in the United States, where economic disparities are among the highest in Western nations (Atkinson et al., Reference Atkinson, Piketty and Saez2011; Neckerman & Torche, Reference Neckerman and Torche2007). Over recent decades, rising disparities have created significant gaps in living conditions (Wilkinson & Pickett, Reference Wilkinson and Pickett2009), with the richest 10% controlling about 70% of wealth while the bottom half owns less than 2% (Chancel et al., Reference Chancel, Piketty, Saez and Zucman2022). These issues are exacerbated by strong socioeconomic segregation (Mijs & Roe, Reference Mijs and Roe2021) and limited social mobility (Hout, Reference Hout2018; OECD, 2018). Despite these economic gaps, public concern about inequality has not risen proportionately (Kenworthy & McCall, Reference Kenworthy and McCall2007; Lierse et al., Reference Lierse, Sachweh and Waitkus2022), with individuals often misunderstanding or underestimating its extent (Chambers et al., Reference Chambers, Swan and Heesacker2014; Trump, Reference Trump2023). The U.S. is an especially relevant context for studying attitudes towards inequality due to its deep disparities and a long tradition of research in this field (e.g., Kluegel & Smith, Reference Kluegel and Smith1981; McCall, Reference McCall2013). Prior studies highlight the U.S. public’s strong belief in meritocracy (Mijs, Reference Mijs2018) and relatively low support for redistribution (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Glaeser and Sacerdote2001; Hoy & Mager, Reference Hoy and Mager2021).
Research on distributive justice has traditionally relied on the latent variable approach, which consolidates multiple perceptions, beliefs, and judgments into mean indexes. This approach often leads to an unsystematic examination of these attitudes, with most studies focusing on only one aspect (Janmaat, Reference Janmaat2013). Moreover, research has primarily focused on the levels of these attitudes (i.e., their public endorsement), often overlooking the cognitive structure in which they are embedded. This is crucial because attitudes do not exist in isolation but are interconnected within a broader belief system (Converse, Reference Converse2006). Recent interdisciplinary research has provided innovative methodologies for analyzing the multifaceted components of attitudes towards inequality and understanding their structural organization. A new scholarship in distributive justice indicates that these attitudes form inequality belief systems, which are mental structures composed of nodes representing survey variables and ties representing their statistical associations in the data (Bertero et al., Reference Bertero, Franetovic and Mijs2024; Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023). Further, research has revealed that the structure of economic attitudes varies across different social strata (DiMaggio & Goldberg, Reference DiMaggio and Goldberg2018; Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023; Hunzaker & Valentino, Reference Hunzaker and Valentino2019). These inquiries complement latent variable approaches by shifting the focus from individuals’ normative views on inequality to understanding how these stances are organized within broader mental structures (Brandt & Sleegers, Reference Brandt and Sleegers2021; Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, van den Berg, Conner and van der Maas2016).
The network approach to studying attitudes towards inequality has two major limitations. First, researchers often split samples into groups to examine belief systems, either by grouping individuals with similar attitudinal structures (DiMaggio & Goldberg, Reference DiMaggio and Goldberg2018; Hunzaker & Valentino, Reference Hunzaker and Valentino2019; Kesberg et al., Reference Kesberg, Brandt, Easterbrook, Spruyt and Turner-Zwinkels2024) or by comparing the belief systems of individuals with different socio-demographic characteristics (Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023; Schlicht-Schmälzle et al., Reference Schlicht-Schmälzle, Chykina and Schmälzle2018). While useful, this reduces statistical power and assumes belief systems differ only between groups, ignoring variations within them. Second, studies rarely examine attitude change, overlooking Converse’s (Reference Converse2006) key proposition that shifts in one belief can realign others. For instance, heightened awareness of income inequality might lead to stronger support for redistributive policies, yet this dynamic remains largely unexplored (Brandt & Sleegers, Reference Brandt and Sleegers2021).
We craft a tripartite analytical strategy to address the limitations in the study of inequality belief systems. First, we model U.S. attitudes towards inequality as a belief system using ISSP data, creating a weighted and signed network that captures the relationships between perceptions, beliefs, and judgments of inequality. Second, we estimate how this structure varies across the population, focusing on the role of anger towards inequality. By applying a Moderated Network Model, we show that angry individuals possess more interconnected and polarized belief system structures. Finally, we simulate attitude change to investigate whether altering central nodes leads to broader adjustments within the belief system.
Our contribution is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the concept of attitudes towards inequality and reviews network approaches to address their structure. Section 3 details the ISSP data and methods used. Section 4 confirms that U.S. attitudes form a small-world inequality belief system centered on income inequality and public redistribution, with significant variations based on anger levels. We also show that changes in central beliefs drive substantial system-wide adaptations. The study concludes with a discussion of its methodological and theoretical contributions and directions for future research.
2. Theory
2.1 Attitudes towards inequality
Attitudes are “general evaluations that people hold regarding a particular entity, such as an object, an issue, or a person” (Lavrakas, Reference Lavrakas2008; p.39). They are evaluative, general, and enduring, making them distinct from moods or rapid impressions. Studied for their strong predictive power of social and political behaviors (Hatemi & McDermott, Reference Hatemi and McDermott2016), attitudes are typically measured through surveys using Multi-Item Likert scales, where responses are summed or weighted to represent an individual’s stance.
Particularly, attitudes towards inequality represent a multifaceted concept, including perceptions, beliefs, and judgments about the distribution of resources within a society (Janmaat, Reference Janmaat2013). Perceptions refer to subjective estimations about the scope of inequality (Castillo et al., Reference Castillo, García-Castro and Venegas2022; Heiserman & Simpson, Reference Heiserman and Simpson2021). Instead, beliefs correspond to normative ideas about how inequality ought to be. Indeed, this dimension is frequently measured with indicators similar to the ones of perceptions, but situating individuals in an ideal scenario (Osberg & Smeeding, Reference Osberg and Smeeding2006). Finally, judgments represent evaluations of existing inequality and refer to how good, desirable, fair, or just individuals rate the current distribution (Kelley & Evans, Reference Kelley and Evans1993).
Inequalities stem from various social, economic, and political arrangements (McCall & Percheski, Reference McCall and Percheski2010), making several interconnected fields crucial for understanding attitudes towards inequality (McCarty & Pontusson, Reference McCarty and Pontusson2011). The way welfare states collect and redistribute resources through social programs and transfers significantly shapes societal inequality (Esping-Andersen & Myles, Reference Esping-Andersen and Myles2011; Korpi & Palme, Reference Korpi and Palme1998; Volscho & Kelly, Reference Volscho and Kelly2012). Additionally, evaluations of taxes, redistribution, and wages are closely tied to perceptions, beliefs, and judgments about inequality (Bartels, Reference Bartels2005; Berens & Gelepithis, Reference Berens and Gelepithis2019; Bussolo et al., Reference Bussolo, Ferrer-i-Carbonell, Giolbas and Torre2021; Choi, Reference Choi2021; Fatke, Reference Fatke2018; García-Sánchez et al., Reference García-Sánchez, Osborne, Willis and Rodríguez-Bailón2020; Iacono & Ranaldi, Reference Iacono and Ranaldi2021; Trump, Reference Trump2023). Understanding inequality thus requires delving into subjective perceptions of these interconnected issues. Indeed, the literature highlights various connections between perceptions, beliefs, and judgments about inequality, taxes, redistribution, and wages. For instance, individual perceptions of inequality influence normative ideas about how society should be structured (Pedersen & Mutz, Reference Pedersen and Mutz2019), support for public redistribution (Gimpelson & Treisman, Reference Gimpelson and Treisman2018; Kuhn, Reference Kuhn2011; Kuziemko et al., Reference Kuziemko, Norton, Saez and Stantcheva2015; Trump, Reference Trump2023), and attitudes towards progressive taxation (García-Sánchez et al., Reference García-Sánchez, Osborne, Willis and Rodríguez-Bailón2020).
These cognitive evaluations are also shaped by emotional responses. Anger plays a crucial role in shaping attitudes towards inequality, yet remains understudied in social justice research. U.S. citizens with lower social status report higher levels of anger, often driven by frustration, inferiority, and perceived injustice (Park et al., Reference Park, Kitayama, Markus, Coe, Miyamoto, Karasawa, Curhan, Love, Kawakami, Boylan and Ryff2013). Anger not only reflects personal grievances but also has broader societal implications. Comparative studies reveal that angry individuals are less likely to support conservative economic parties and more likely to back progressive ones (Gonthier, Reference Gonthier2023). It strengthens the link between perceptions of inequality and the willingness to engage in political action (Leach et al., Reference Leach, Iyer and Pedersen2006) and mediates the relationship between perceived inequalities and psychological well-being (Vezzoli et al., Reference Vezzoli, Valtorta, Mari, Durante and Volpato2023). These findings suggest that anger amplifies connections between distributive evaluations, moderating the structure of inequality belief systems.
Beyond cross-sectional studies, researchers have also examined how attitudes towards inequality evolve, yielding mixed results. Cruces and colleagues (Reference Cruces, Perez-Truglia and Tetaz2013), using an experimental survey in Argentina, demonstrated the significant role of perceptions in shaping distributional beliefs. Their findings revealed that individuals who overestimated their relative social position became more supportive of redistribution when informed of their actual placement in the social hierarchy. Similarly, Campos-Vazquez et al. (Reference Campos-Vazquez, Krozer, Ramírez-Álvarez, De La Torre and Velez-Grajales2022) conducted an experimental study in Mexico, providing participants with objective information about income inequality and social mobility. Unlike the Argentine study, their results showed that altering perceptions of inequality did not lead to changes in participants’ normative beliefs about income distribution, social mobility, or tax rates.
2.2 Inequality belief systems
In response to the unsystematic nature of previous research, a new strand of the literature has emerged, examining the structure of attitudes towards inequality (Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023). This approach focuses on how perceptions, beliefs, and judgments about economic disparities, redistribution, taxation, and wage allocation interact to form an interconnected inequality belief system (Bertero et al., Reference Bertero, Franetovic and Mijs2024). This approach, rooted in the work of Converse (Reference Converse2006), complements the traditional latent variable model commonly used in attitude research. Latent models conceptualize attitudes as unobservable constructs that are reflected in observable evaluations of attitude objects (Eagly & Chaiken, Reference Eagly and Chaiken1993; Rosenberg, Reference Rosenberg1960). They rely on assumptions of local independence—where observed indicators are thought not to influence each other once the latent attitude is accounted for—and exchangeability—where adding more items only enhances reliability without contributing new information (Bagozzi, Reference Bagozzi1981; Bollen, Reference Bollen1989; Bollen & Lennox, Reference Bollen and Lennox1991).
The belief system literature incorporates cognitive consistency and accuracy as core mechanisms, suggesting that attitudes develop incrementally through associations with related beliefs (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, van den Berg, Conner and van der Maas2016). For instance, individuals might first perceive high levels of income inequality and judge them as fair or unfair (Time 1). Over time, they could associate this judgment with beliefs about the causes of inequality, such as the gender pay gap (Time 2), and later expand these associations to include political inaction (Time 3) or the role of race and religion in personal success (Times 4 and 5). In this process, individuals aim to minimize cognitive inconsistency by forming coherent stances on subjective inequality (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, Waldorp and van der Maas2017). However, belief systems must also balance consistency with accuracy, allowing for misaligned evaluations. For example, individuals might believe inequality is high due to the gender pay gap but see race and religion as irrelevant to the inequality equation.
This dual process generates two patterns. First, the expansion of belief systems involves nodes unequally, as some components—like those with strong initial associations—are more likely to connect with newer perceptions, beliefs, and judgments, resembling patterns of preferential attachment (Barabási & Albert, Reference Barabási and Albert1999; Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, van den Berg, Conner and van der Maas2016, Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2018). Consequently, beliefs differ in centrality within the network. Second, aligned and misaligned evaluations are organized to coexist without psychological distress. To achieve this, belief systems exhibit high clustering, grouping coherent evaluations within the same substructures while placing mismatched ones in distinct areas of the network (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2019).
Researchers in this field have primarily used two methodologies. On the one hand, scholars have used Correlational Class Analysis (CCA; Boutyline, Reference Boutyline2017) or Relational Class Analysis (RCA; Goldberg, Reference Goldberg2011). These techniques group individuals based on similar correlational patterns among their attitudes, mapping belief systems as networks of associations without assuming shared normative positions. For example, Kesberg et al. (Reference Kesberg, Brandt, Easterbrook, Spruyt and Turner-Zwinkels2024) applied CCA to examine the validity of system justification theory (Jost & Van der Toorn, Reference Jost and van der Toorn2012), finding that social status negatively correlates with support for the status quo only within specific population segments, not universally. Using RCA, DiMaggio & Goldberg (Reference DiMaggio and Goldberg2018) identified three distinct ways the U.S. public organizes attitudes towards the market: an “economistic” class favoring markets as beneficial, a “hostile worlds” class supporting markets but restricting morally contentious transactions (e.g., organ sales), and a “progressive” class endorsing markets with regulatory interventions to address market failures and protect public welfare.
A second class of network methods, introduced by Boutyline & Vaisey (Reference Boutyline and Vaisey2017) and refined through advancements in network psychometrics (Borsboom et al., Reference Borsboom, Deserno, Rhemtulla, Epskamp, Fried, McNally, Robinaugh, Perugini, Dalege, Costantini, Isvoranu, Wysocki, van Borkulo, van Bork and Waldorp2021) and political psychology (Brandt, Reference Brandt2022; Brandt et al., Reference Brandt, Sibley and Osborne2019), represents attitudes as nodes within weighted and signed networks, with edges indicating partial correlations between survey items. Franetovic & Bertero (Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023) applied this approach to study inequality attitudes in Chile, revealing an integrated belief system with a small-world structure. They also found that lower social groups exhibit higher connectivity, a feature linked to attitude strength (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2019). Combining CCA with partial correlation networks, Bertero et al. (Reference Bertero, Franetovic and Mijs2024) identified two distinct types of belief systems in the U.S. and the Netherlands, showing that the organization of these systems significantly predicts support for public redistribution.
2.3 Research hypotheses
This section outlines our research hypotheses. Attitudes are conceptualized as networks of evaluations, where some nodes form more connections, bridging areas of the network and enhancing connectivity. These networks are typically clustered to balance accuracy and consistency, resembling small-world structures (Watts & Strogatz, Reference Watts and Strogatz1998). Small-world properties have been reported across various contexts, including attitudes towards political candidates (Dalege, et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2017; Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, Waldorp and van der Maas2017; Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, van den Berg, Conner and van der Maas2016) post-national citizenship identities (Schlicht-Schmälzle et al., Reference Schlicht-Schmälzle, Chykina and Schmälzle2018), job satisfaction (Carter et al., Reference Carter, Lowery, Williamson Smith, Conley, Harris, Listyg, Maupin, King and Carter2020), bio-based plastic (Zwicker et al., Reference Zwicker, Nohlen, Dalege, Gruter and van Harreveld2020), political values (Turner-Zwinkels et al., Reference Turner-Zwinkels, Johnson, Sibley and Brandt2020), and inequality (Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023). Based on this, we hypothesize:
H1: The inequality belief system will exhibit a small-world structure.
Beliefs differ in importance. For networks estimated with cross-sectional data, centrality reflects how strongly a node interacts with others, without indicating directionality—it may predict, be predicted by, or both (Bringmann et al., Reference Bringmann, Elmer, Epskamp, Krause, Schoch, Wichers, Wigman and Snippe2019). In social justice research, the perception of large income inequality is often treated as an independent variable, influencing attitudes like support for redistribution (Gimpelson & Treisman, Reference Gimpelson and Treisman2018; Trump, Reference Trump2023), ideal distributions (Pedersen & Mutz, Reference Pedersen and Mutz2019), and progressive taxation (García-Sánchez et al., Reference García-Sánchez, Osborne, Willis and Rodríguez-Bailón2020). Conversely, the belief in public redistribution is typically a dependent variable shaped by factors such as social class (Langsæther & Evans, Reference Langsæther and Evans2020), subjective social status (Choi, Reference Choi2021), beliefs about intergenerational mobility (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Stantcheva and Teso2018), social comparison processes (García-Castro et al., Reference García-Castro, García-Sánchez, Montoya-Lozano and Rodríguez-Bailón2022), and trust in the political system (Franetovic & Castillo, Reference Franetovic and Castillo2022). These two attitudes are positively correlated (Gimpelson & Treisman, Reference Gimpelson and Treisman2018; Kuhn, Reference Kuhn2011; Kuziemko et al., Reference Kuziemko, Norton, Saez and Stantcheva2015; Trump, Reference Trump2023) and play a pivotal role in distributive justice research. Notably, Franetovic & Bertero (Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023) found them to be the most central nodes in Chile’s inequality belief system. Therefore:
H2: Perception of large income inequality and belief in public redistribution will be the most central nodes in the inequality belief system.
The first two hypotheses examine the attitudinal structure at the population level, yet full-sample data may obscure structural heterogeneities (DiMaggio et al., Reference DiMaggio, Sotoudeh, Goldberg and Shepherd2018). Social positions influence relational structures, with lower income, education, and social class linked to more densely connected inequality belief systems (Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023). Anger might play a central role in shaping these systems, reinforcing the connections between distributive attitudes. Indeed, anger was observed to promote greater consistency between implicit and explicit attitudes by fostering a sense of certainty (Huntsinger, Reference Huntsinger2013). The neural basis of anger’s influence further underscores its critical role: anger enhances certainty through activation of brain regions associated with confidence (Luttrell et al., Reference Luttrell, Stillman, Hasinski and Cunningham2016). Furthermore, anger stabilizes attitudes by increasing emotional involvement, which reduces susceptibility to change over time (Rocklage & Luttrell, Reference Rocklage and Luttrell2021). As an active emotion, anger increases attitude-behavior consistency by energizing individuals to act in line with their beliefs (Seitz et al., Reference Seitz, Lord and Taylor2007). Moreover, anger mobilizes individuals by sharpening selective cognitive processing, which polarizes belief systems and reinforces attitude interconnections (Pomerantz et al., Reference Pomerantz, Chaiken and Tordesillas1995). Together, these findings emphasize anger can be expected to relate with attitude strength. Therefore:
H3: Anger towards inequality will consolidate the structure of the inequality belief system, such that negative relationships will become more negative and positive relationships will become more positive.
Network approaches to belief systems provide a formalized theory of attitude change. Nodes vary in centrality, and changes in central nodes are expected to produce larger shifts in the network compared to peripheral ones (Brandt et al., Reference Brandt, Sibley and Osborne2019; Converse, Reference Converse2006). This has been confirmed through simulations, where changes in central nodes create downstream effects, causing neighboring nodes to adjust their states (Dalege, et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2017; Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, Waldorp and van der Maas2017). Similar effects, albeit weaker, have been observed in longitudinal studies of job satisfaction (Carter et al., Reference Carter, Lowery, Williamson Smith, Conley, Harris, Listyg, Maupin, King and Carter2020), COVID-19-related attitudes (Chambon et al., Reference Chambon, Dalege, Waldorp, Van der Maas, Borsboom, van Harreveld and Spruyt2022), and political beliefs (Turner-Zwinkels & Brandt, Reference Turner-Zwinkels and Brandt2022). Given the scarcity of panel data for a large set of variables on subjective inequality—and cumulating with H2—this study simulates manipulations targeting each node to test whether:
H4: Simulated manipulation attempts targeting the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution will produce downstream effects in the inequality belief system.
3. Methods
3.1 Data and variables
We use the ISSP 2019 Social Inequality V module (ISSP Research Group, 2022), which includes several indicators of subjective inequality. We analyze U.S. data, collected with a multistage probabilistic design and Computer Assisted Web Interface methodology. The sample is representative of the population aged 18 years or older. The original dataset includes 1,852 individuals. Table 1 shows the 22 selected variables and their corresponding ISSP questions. High scores indicate progressive positions: high perceptions of inequalities, egalitarian beliefs, and judgments of unfairness about existing levels of social disparities. All variables are measured on a 1 to 5 scale, with the exceptions of Judgment of unfair distribution Footnote 1 (1–4) and Anger towards inequality (0–10). Listwise deletion reduces the sample to 1,188 individualsFootnote 2 .
Table 1. Labels and survey questions. Squared brackets indicate common prompts between different items. The polarity of asterisked variables was inverted to have maximum values aligned with progressive positions: high perception, egalitarian beliefs, and critical judgments of existing inequality

To cumulate with past research, the article includes twelve perceptions, seven beliefs, and three judgments about inequality in the U.S. (see Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023). Respondents were asked to report their Perception of large income inequality and their Perception of tax regressivity. The analyses further include ten explanations of inequality, also known as inequality beliefs (Mijs, Reference Mijs2018), which are items asking respondents to indicate how important they perceive a set of structural and individual factors to be for getting ahead in life (Importance of wealthy family, parental education, own education, hard work, knowing the right people, political connections, giving bribes, personal race, religion, and sex). Belief items ask respondents to express normative judgments on how they would desire society to be organized. The questionnaire included the Belief in progressive taxation, public redistribution, and market redistribution. Moreover, one survey battery taps into beliefs on just pay criteria, asking respondents to indicate whether they would agree on wages to be regulated based on the responsibility associated with the job, or on workers’ training levels, needs, and merits (responsibility, training, need, merit). Finally, respondents judged the fairness of the existing income distribution in the U.S. (Judgment of unfair distribution), the extent to which politicians are distrusted (Judgment of political distrust in redistribution), and unsuccessful (Judgment of failure of public redistribution) in addressing and fighting inequality. Finally, the 2019 ISSP Social Inequality module measures, for the first time, individuals’ anger towards inequality. This item is addressed with the following survey question: “Some people feel angry about differences in wealth between the rich and the poor, while others do not. How do you feel when you think about differences in wealth between the rich and the poor in the U.S.?”.
3.2 Network estimation
Network estimation follows several steps (Borsboom et al., Reference Borsboom, Deserno, Rhemtulla, Epskamp, Fried, McNally, Robinaugh, Perugini, Dalege, Costantini, Isvoranu, Wysocki, van Borkulo, van Bork and Waldorp2021). Variables are first selected through a literature review to ensure construct validity. Survey data is then analyzed using Graphical Models, which encode conditional dependencies as network edges and independencies as their absence (Lauritzen, Reference Lauritzen1996). The resulting undirected network represents the aggregate structure of the U.S. inequality belief system. Structural properties are analyzed, and parameter stability is tested using bootstrapping (Efron, Reference Efron1979).
To address H1 and H2, a Mixed Graphical Model (mgm) is estimated (Haslbeck & Waldorp, Reference Haslbeck and Waldorp2020). This model accommodates variables measured at different scales and estimates parameters through a series of node-wise regularized linear regressions. At the beginning of the analysis, variables are mean-centered and rescaled. Then, each variable is iteratively regressed on every other, while controlling for the remaining nodes. To enable variable selection and promote model parsimony, mgm uses L1-penalized regression (LASSO) (Tibshirani, Reference Tibshirani1996). LASSO regularization induces sparsity in the network matrix, as it forces smaller coefficients to become exactly zero, effectively performing variable selection. The LASSO tuning parameter is searched with a model selection approach and is found by minimizing the Extended Bayesian Information Criterion (Chen, Reference Chen and Chen2008), an extension of the BIC (Schwarz, Reference Schwarz1978) that penalizes with additional intensity nonzero parameters. This strategy is extensively validated (Epskamp & Fried, Reference Epskamp and Fried2018; Foygel & Drton, Reference Foygel, Drton, Lafferty, Williams, Shawe-Taylor, Zemel and Culotta2010; Haslbeck & Waldorp, Reference Haslbeck and Waldorp2020) and allows the quantification of node predictability. Since all variables are modeled as continuous, R2 values are reported, and edges are interpretable as regularized linear regression coefficients (Burger et al., Reference Burger, Isvoranu, Lunansky, Haslbeck, Epskamp, Hoekstra, Fried, Borsboom and Blanken2023).
H1 and H2 are tested on the mgm networkFootnote 3 . The small-worldness of the network, assessed using Telesford et al.’s (Reference Telesford, Joyce, Hayasaka, Burdette and Laurienti2011) test, compares clustering and connectivity with a lattice network of the same size. Clustering measures the extent to which nodes form cliques (Watts & Strogatz, Reference Watts and Strogatz1998), and connectivity is evaluated via the Average Shortest Path LengthFootnote 4 (ASPL). Networks are small-world if their connectivity matches or exceeds a random network and their clustering is higher, producing values between −0.5 and +0.5. The centrality of network nodes is calculated with the Strength metric, which sums the absolute values of the edge weights of the relationships in which a node is involved (Opsahl et al., Reference Opsahl, Agneessens and Skvoretz2010). Strength captures direct, pairwise associations between attitudes, providing a robust measure of each node’s importance within the inequality belief systemFootnote 5 .
H3 investigates whether the network structure estimated on the full sample hides structural heterogeneities that are produced by different levels of anger towards inequality. A common approach for testing research questions involving group differences is to split the sample by the levels of a third variable, estimate two network models, and compare them with a permutation-based Network Comparison Test (van Borkulo et al., Reference van Borkulo, van Bork, Boschloo, Kossakowski, Tio, Schoevers, Borsboom and Waldorp2022). The split-sample strategy is commonly used by scholars employing a network approach to examine the structure of socio-political attitudes. Yet, these procedures are impeded by two shortcomings. First, data-split approaches reduce sample size, and thus statistical leverage; second, these strategies can only model a step moderation process, where the slope of a relationship can differ between two groups, but not within them. The Moderated Network Model (MNM) mitigates both problems (Haslbeck et al., Reference Haslbeck, Borsboom and Waldorp2021). Its edges are estimated with the same strategy outlined above, relying on a set of regularized linear regressions whose tuning parameter is obtained by minimizing the EBIC. However, in each of these regressions, the MNM adds a moderation effect of a selected variable. Therefore, MNM produces two parameter matrices, one for the pairwise and one for the three-way interactions. To address H3, this article fits an MNM in which anger towards inequality is specified as a moderator. H3 is confirmed if anger meaningfully moderates network edges.
H4 is tested with a network simulation that requires variables’ dichotomizationFootnote 6 . Edges of this model represent associations between binary nodes and are estimated with logistic—rather than linear—regularized regressions. Hence, the mgm reduces to an Ising model (Ising, Reference Ising1925), whose edges are interpretable as logistic regression coefficients (van Borkulo et al., Reference van Borkulo, Borsboom, Epskamp, Blanken, Boschloo, Schoevers and Waldorp2015). The Ising model can estimate two additional classes of parameters that are discussed in Section 3.3.
We evaluate the robustness of edge weights (Figures 2 and 4, Supplemental Material) and of the moderation effects of anger (Table 2, Supplemental Material) with non-parametric bootstrapping (Epskamp et al., Reference Epskamp, Borsboom and Fried2018), generating 10,000 resamples on which we re-estimate networks, to estimate 95% confidence intervals. Strength centrality stability is tested with case-dropping bootstraps, yielding the Correlation Stability (CS) coefficient, which should exceed 0.25, preferably 0.50. Bootstrapped difference tests compare edges or Strength scores, with non-overlapping intervals indicating significant differences.
Last, we adopt community detection techniques to investigate how nodes of the inequality belief system cluster together. To cumulate with the partial-correlation-based Exploratory Graph Analysis (EGA) technique, we adopt the Walktrap community detection algorithm (Golino et al., Reference Golino, Shi, Christensen, Garrido, Nieto, Sadana, Thiyagarajan and Martinez-Molina2020, p. 202; Golino et al., Reference Golino, Epskamp and Voracek2017)Footnote 7 . In the remainder of the Methods section, we detail our simulation of attitude change.
3.3 Network simulation
H4 is tested through a simulation of network dynamics using Ising’s model (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2017; Ising, Reference Ising1925), where nodes represent endorsement or rejection of survey items (−1 or + 1). The temperature parameter, governing system entropy, remains constant across simulations due to its correlation with attitude strength (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2018). Two additional parameters, described by the Hamiltonian function, estimate the energy expenditure of the network configuration:

Each network node (Xi to Xj) has a threshold (
$\boldsymbol\tau$
i to
$\boldsymbol\tau$
j) ranging from −1 to + 1, indicating its likelihood of being endorsed (+1) or not (−1). The ω parameter models the strength of nodes interactions, with positive values for positive associations and vice versa. Configurations of the belief system where nodes with positive thresholds are connected with positive edges minimize energy expenditure, aligning with the Ising model’s principle that attitudes favor low-energy configurations.
The simulation models persuasion attempts targeting one node at a time and has already been applied to socio-political attitudes (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld and van der Maas2017; Schlicht-Schmälzle et al., Reference Schlicht-Schmälzle, Chykina and Schmälzle2018). Manipulations increase node thresholds (
$\boldsymbol\tau$
), with the dependent variable being the sum score of attitudes towards inequalityFootnote
8
before and after each manipulation. H4 is supported if changes in the perception of large income inequality and belief in public redistribution cause downstream effects, where a node’s state change influences others. The simulation creates 23 samples of 3,000 individuals answering 22 survey items. In the baseline, all nodes have a threshold of −0.1; in all other samples, one node is set to + 1Footnote
9
. Networks are estimated after each iteration, and sum scores are compared to assess structural changes.
4. Results
4.1 Modeling the inequality belief systems
Table 1 in the Supplemental Material shows descriptives of the 22 attitudes. U.S. citizens widely perceive economic disparities, support egalitarian distribution, and view current inequalities as unfair. They see income inequality as significant, the tax system as regressive, and success as mostly tied to hard work and education. Respondents favor progressive taxation, expect action from corporations and public institutions to reduce income differences, and prioritize merit in wage allocation. They also view political actors as disinterested and ineffective in addressing inequalities.
Figure 1 illustrates the U.S. inequality belief system, with nodes representing the 22 perceptions, beliefs, and judgments, colored according to community detection results. The network is visualized using a force-directed layout (Fruchterman & Reingold, Reference Fruchterman and Reingold1991), with edges indicating positive (blue) or negative (red) associations between items. The attitudes form a single, cohesive belief system, showing that U.S. citizens organize their views on inequality, taxation, redistribution, and wages into one mental framework.

Figure 1. Inequality belief system – mgm. Variables are represented as nodes, which are connected by weighted and signed edges. Nodes are colored according to community detection results. The circular shape around each node plots the partition of its variance that is explained by the model. Ties are indicative of the unique variance shared between each item pair. Their width is proportional to the strength of the corresponding associations. Blue edges represent positive linear influences, red negative ones.
The strongest positive associations in the model link explanations based on race and sex, political connections and knowing the right people, and perception of large income inequality with support for public redistribution. The strongest negative associations in the network are those between explanations considering the importance of hard work and giving bribes, inequality beliefs pointing at the importance of wealthy families and hard work, and between the belief in public redistribution and responsibility as pay criteria.
Network edges reveal two main patterns. First, most associations are positive, reflecting the coherent organization of U.S. citizens’ high perceptions, egalitarian beliefs, and severe judgments about inequality. Second, the strongest connections occur between variables within the same conceptual domain. For example, pay criteria such as merit, responsibility, and training are strongly linked, as are the ten explanations of inequality, clustered at the bottom of Figure 1.
Structuralist explanations like religion, race, and sex are more likely to interact with each other than with individualist factors like hard work or education. Moreover, we also retrieve strong associations between different types of attitudes towards inequality, such as those between the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution, or between the perception of tax regressivity and the belief in progressive taxation. Moreover, believing in need as a pay criterion is largely unrelated to endorsing merit or responsibility. Therefore, not all semantically related attitudes strongly correlate.
These associations create four distinct network communities, each representing different domains of attitudes towards inequality. The structuralist community (yellow) focuses on societal divisions that contribute to inequality, such as race, religion, and sex. The individualist community (green) centers on factors tied to individual agency, including hard work, education, and responsibility, merit, and training as pay criteria. The mixed community (blue) encompasses meso-level explanations rooted in social contexts, such as the importance of knowing the right people, having political connections, or coming from a wealthy family. Lastly, the red community includes all judgments, perceptions, and beliefs related to both public and private redistribution.
Node predictability measures how much of a variable’s variance is explained by the network model. Pay criteria show the lowest predictability, suggesting they are less integrated into the network and influenced by factors external to the model. In contrast, the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution have the highest predictability, indicating that their levels are primarily determined by other variables included in the network model. This supports the validity of item selection, as key variables in inequality research are well-modeled by the inequality belief system.
According to belief system theory, this system is expected to exhibit a small-world structure (H1), balancing individuals’ needs for accuracy and consistency. Structurally, the network shows low density, with only 30.6% of possible edges present. Compared to a random network, it has a higher average shortest path length (ASPL) and lower clustering coefficient, resulting in a small-world score of 0.228, confirming H1.
We also hypothesize that the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution are the most central nodes (H2). Figure 2 shows their high Strength centrality scores, indicating strong and frequent connections with other nodes. These variables consistently rank as the most central in both the full-scale and bootstrapped networks, with the belief in public redistribution slightly more central overall. Notably, centrality stability is high, with results remaining reliable even when 75% of the sample is dropped. Peripheral nodes include the four pay criteria and the belief in market redistribution, showing that high endorsement does not guarantee centrality. For example, while the support for market redistribution has a higher average endorsement than public redistribution, the latter is far more central, underscoring its pivotal role in the inequality belief system.

Figure 2. Strength centrality of mgm’s nodes. Each row shows one node and its centrality, measured in z-scores.
These results confirm that U.S. attitudes towards inequality form a cohesive belief system with a small-world structure (H1), where the perception of large income inequality and belief in public redistribution are the most central nodes (H2). The system clusters into four communities: structuralist, individualist, mixed explanations, and redistributive beliefs, with most associations being positive and reinforcing coherent attitudinal patterns. Furthermore, pay criteria remain weakly embedded, while redistributive attitudes are highly interconnected, underscoring their central role in inequality belief systems.
4.2 Exploring the impact of anger on the inequality belief system
Figure 3 confirms our hypothesis (H3) that anger towards inequality moderates the belief system’s structure. Each panel shows networks estimated at different anger levels, with anger depicted as a separate white node. More than 25 edges are strongly influenced by anger, as detailed in Table 2 of the Supplemental Material, with effects consistently found in over 83% of bootstrapped samples, ensuring robust results.

Figure 3. Inequality belief system at varying levels of anger towards inequality – MNM. Each panel shows the result of a mgm estimation at a fixed level of the moderating variable, anger. Nodes are colored according to their classification in perceptions, beliefs, and judgments. Anger is plotted in white for clarity. Weighted and signed edges indicate conditional associations. Moderation effects are detectable by observing variations in edge color and/or width.
The strongest moderation effect involves the relationship between the judgment on the failure of public redistribution and the belief in public redistribution. The magnitude of this moderation effect equals 0.064. Indeed, when anger scores zero, a unit increase in the belief in public redistribution corresponds to a 0.025-unit increase in the judgment of its failure. As anger rises, this relationship strengthens. For example, when anger scores 3 (top-right panel of Figure 3), the relationship increases to 0.217, reaching 0.473 and 0.665 in the bottom panels. This moderation shows that anger towards inequality amplifies the link between these variables. Therefore, Figure 3 underscores that the associations between distributive attitudes are generally stronger for individuals who are angry towards inequality.
Anger strongly moderates relationships between explanations of inequality. As anger increases, distinctions between individualist, structuralist, and mixed explanations become more pronounced. For example, at low anger, perceiving a wealthy family as important weakly predicts considering sex as significant, but this link strengthens significantly at high anger. Similarly, the connection between perceiving the importance of coming from a wealthy family and political connections grows for angry individuals. In contrast, anger sharpens divides between structuralist and individualist factors. For example, when anger is low, parental education and race are unconnected, but at high anger, they are strongly and negatively connected. Similarly, the weak negative association between personal education and giving bribes becomes strongly opposed.
Anger also alters the role of specific variables, such as the importance of education and the belief in market redistribution. At low anger, education is weakly associated with the belief in market redistribution, but this link becomes much stronger at high anger. As a result, the belief in market redistribution, typically peripheral in the network, becomes more central when anger is high, interacting more strongly with other perceptions and beliefs.
At low levels of anger (top panels of Figure 3), the inequality belief system mirrors the full sample network (Figure 1), with four distinct network communities. However, as anger increases, the network consolidates into fewer communities, reflecting stronger interactions among distributive attitudes. When individuals experience higher anger (bottom panels of Figure 3), their belief system is structured into three communities, with explanations of inequality merging into a single group. This suggests that heightened anger drives U.S. citizens to see individual, structural, and mixed factors as increasingly interconnected in shaping social inequalities.
Anger intensifies most of the associations within the network, making attitudes towards inequality more contentious. Indeed, at low anger, the networks show weaker connections and fewer negative associations; for example, mean absolute edge weights are 0.061 and 0.068, with 46 and 59 negative edges when anger scores 0 and 3. At higher anger (scores 7 and 10), mean edge weights increase to 0.101 and 0.127, and negative edges rise to 62 and 63. This intensification means positive associations become stronger, while null or weakly negative relationships turn strongly negative, leading to a more polarized and tightly connected belief system.
The results confirm that anger towards inequality significantly moderates the structure of the belief system (H3), strengthening over 25 edges and consolidating attitudes into fewer, more interconnected communities. The strongest moderation effect links the belief in public redistribution with judgments of its failure, with this association intensifying as anger increases. Anger also sharpens the divide between structuralist and individualist explanations, making attitudes more polarized. At higher anger levels, previously weak or null associations become strongly negative, reinforcing a more contentious and tightly connected belief system.
4.3 Simulating attitude change
To test whether changes in central nodes trigger larger adjustments than peripheral ones, variables were dichotomized, and an Ising simulation was conducted. Table 1 in the Supplemental Material provides descriptives, and Figure 4 shows the resulting network (top) and node strength centrality (bottom).

Figure 4. Inequality belief system and node centrality – Ising. The top panel shows the results of the Ising estimation. The bottom panel shows z-scores of strength centrality.
In Figure 4, edges represent regularized logistic regression coefficients, with the layout replicating Figure 1 for comparability. The Ising network has similar density (0.32) and retains the strongest associations from the full-scale model, such as links between race and sex, tax regressivity and progressive taxation, and large income inequality and public redistribution. Strength scores and communities remain consistent, with the perception of large income inequality, the importance of race, and the belief in public redistribution as the most central nodes, while pay criteria and the belief in market redistribution are the most peripheral.
Figure 1 in the Supplemental Material compares standardized centrality scores from the two models, showing minimal variation in rankings. The main exception is the belief in public redistribution, which ranks first in the mgm network but third in the Ising model. In both models, the perception of large income inequality, the importance of race, the belief in public redistribution, and the importance of wealthy families consistently score highest in centrality, with overlapping bootstrapped confidence intervals for most differences. However, the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution remain more central than all other nodes. Furthermore, the CS coefficient remains high (0.75), and the Ising network is confirmed to have a small-world structure (0.223).
H4 predicts that changes in central nodes will produce downstream effects, triggering broader adjustments in the inequality belief system. To test this, we simulate manipulations targeting one node at a time by increasing its threshold—a parameter modeling the predisposition to endorse each attitude—from −0.1 to +1, while keeping the thresholds of other nodes fixed at −0.1. According to the Hamiltonian function, increasing a node’s threshold does not guarantee a state change (i.e., from “not endorsed” to “endorsed”), as nodes are influenced not only by their predisposition but also by their connections to other nodes (ω parameter).
Figure 5 presents the results of the simulated manipulations through a forest plot showing the network sum scores after each intervention. When all thresholds are set to a moderately negative value (−0.1), the network sum score is −5.462 (CI = −5.721, −5.203), indicating a moderately negative configuration of attitudes. This additive index ranges from −22 (rejection of all items) to +22 (endorsement of all items).

Figure 5. Network sum scores after simulated manipulation attempts. Each row is associated with a simulated manipulation attempt targeting one network node. Dots and confidence intervals show the mean sum score of the Ising network after each intervention. The dashed line on the left separates successful versus unsuccessful manipulations. The dotted line on the right represents the threshold for downstream effects.
The dashed reference line in Figure 5 distinguishes between successful and unsuccessful manipulations. All dots have confidence intervals to the right of this line, indicating that each manipulation significantly altered the network sum score. A dotted reference line, placed 2 units further to the right, highlights downstream effects. Nodes with confidence intervals beyond this line not only changed their state but also triggered broader adjustments in the network, reflecting downstream effects on the inequality belief system.
Eight nodes produce changes exceeding two units, confirming and extending H4. These include the perception of large income inequality, the importance of race, coming from a wealthy family, and personal sex, the belief in public redistribution and progressive taxation, the perception of tax regressivity, and the judgment of failure of public redistribution. A comparison between Figure 5 and the centrality table in Figure 4 shows a strong correlation between Strength centrality and the magnitude of sum score changes, as the most central nodes tend to produce the largest downstream effects. Exceptions include the judgment of failure of public redistribution and the importance of sex, which have moderate centrality but still trigger substantial network changes when manipulated.
The simulation confirms that changes in central nodes produce downstream effects in the inequality belief system (H4). The Ising model retains the core structure of the full-scale network, with large income inequality and belief in public redistribution remaining the most influential nodes. Manipulations targeting central nodes lead to widespread attitude shifts, while peripheral nodes have limited impact. Eight nodes, including inequality perceptions, redistributive beliefs, and structural explanations, produce the largest changes, reinforcing the strong link between centrality and attitude change.
5. Discussion
This study demonstrates that attitudes towards inequality in the U.S. form a cohesive inequality belief system, encompassing evaluations of social disparities, redistribution, taxation, and wages as interrelated topics, essential for understanding distributive attitudes (Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023). The belief system is organized into four network communities: views on inequality, which include perceptions of income disparities and unfair distributions; individualist explanations, such as the role of hard work and education; structuralist explanations, focusing on societal factors like race and gender; and mixed explanations, addressing the importance of political connections or coming from a wealthy family. The inequality belief system exhibits a small-world structure, a property validated across diverse attitudinal domains (Carter et al., Reference Carter, Lowery, Williamson Smith, Conley, Harris, Listyg, Maupin, King and Carter2020; Schlicht-Schmälzle et al., Reference Schlicht-Schmälzle, Chykina and Schmälzle2018; Turner-Zwinkels et al., Reference Turner-Zwinkels, Johnson, Sibley and Brandt2020; Zwicker et al., Reference Zwicker, Nohlen, Dalege, Gruter and van Harreveld2020). The small-world structure reflects a balance between consistency and accuracy: strongly aligned attitudes cluster together, while weaker or conflicting evaluations remain segregated (Dalege et al., Reference Dalege, Borsboom, van Harreveld, van den Berg, Conner and van der Maas2016). This organization underscores the complexity of public attitudes in the U.S., where deeply rooted beliefs in meritocracy coexist with critical perceptions of inequality. Within this network, the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution were confirmed as the most central nodes, reaffirming their pivotal roles in shaping attitudes towards inequality (Franetovic & Bertero, Reference Franetovic and Bertero2023).
The moderated network model reveals that anger moderates nearly one-third of the edges in the inequality belief system, intensifying both positive and negative associations. This suggests that at higher levels of anger, the belief system consolidates, becoming more polarized and contentious. For example, we found that anger amplifies the relationship between the belief in public redistribution and judgments of its failure. This means that as anger increases, individuals who believe strongly in public redistribution also perceive government efforts to address inequality as more inadequate, reflecting heightened skepticism. Additionally, anger sharpens divisions between structuralist and individualist explanations of inequality, such as the negative relationship between race and education. This highlights the role of anger as an emotion that reinforces cognitive selectivity, organizing attitudes into denser, more polarized clusters. Therefore anger can transform the belief system into a more rigid and contentious structure, where attitudes are both more interconnected and more divergent.
At the full-sample level, our findings align with prior research indicating that individualist and structuralist explanations of inequality typically correlate positively, reflecting a general tendency for people to acknowledge both personal and systemic factors in shaping socioeconomic outcomes (Mijs, Reference Mijs2018). When individuals are content with the level of U.S. inequality, they tend to endorse individualist and structuralist explanations altogether. However, this pattern breaks down among individuals with high levels of anger. In this subgroup, individualist and structuralist explanations exhibit negative correlations, revealing a cognitive divide in how angry individuals reconcile these beliefs. Despite this divergence, the belief in meritocracy—centered on the importance of hard work—consistently correlates positively with other nodes in the inequality belief system, regardless of anger levels.
This finding underscores the enduring salience of meritocratic values in the U.S., where such beliefs are deeply ingrained in public attitudes and serve as a key lens for understanding inequality (Alesina & Glaeser, Reference Alesina and Glaeser2004; McCall, Reference McCall2013; Shariff et al., Reference Shariff, Wiwad and Aknin2016). Notably, this pattern contrasts with findings from other countries, such as the Netherlands, where meritocracy is negatively linked to progressive attitudes toward diversity and heightened perceptions of inequality (Bertero et al., Reference Bertero, Franetovic and Mijs2024). In highly unequal societies, meritocratic beliefs often function less as an aspiration for fairness and more as a justification for existing disparities (Mijs, Reference Mijs2019). This dynamic helps explain why, despite extreme levels of inequality, the U.S. public remains resistant to redistributive policies, as success is framed primarily through personal responsibility rather than structural privilege (McCall, Reference McCall2013). Unlike in more egalitarian contexts, where meritocratic ideals can align with progressive views on inequality, in the U.S., they act as a stabilizing force, reinforcing the legitimacy of economic disparities and shaping how fairness and opportunity are perceived. Thus, inequality belief systems are not solely a reflection of economic conditions but are also shaped by cultural narratives that define how success is understood and legitimized.
Our simulation of attitude change provides evidence for Converse’s (Reference Converse2006) ideas on belief system dynamics, showing that central nodes have significant downstream effects (Chambon et al., Reference Chambon, Dalege, Waldorp, Van der Maas, Borsboom, van Harreveld and Spruyt2022). Specifically, targeting the perception of large income inequality or the belief in public redistribution produces the largest shifts in the network, reaffirming their pivotal roles. These findings align with experiments in the social justice literature, which show that increasing awareness of income inequality enhances support for redistribution (Cruces et al., Reference Cruces, Perez-Truglia and Tetaz2013; Mijs & Hoy, Reference Mijs and Hoy2022). Notably, our results extend this by revealing broader effects. In our simulation, interventions targeting central nodes influenced not only their levels of endorsement but also those of other distributive attitudes. This suggests that public campaigns or policy measures that influence perceptions of income inequality could have cascading effects, reshaping the broader belief system. For instance, in the U.S. context, where support for redistribution remains low compared to other Western democracies (Alesina et al., Reference Alesina, Glaeser and Sacerdote2001) targeted interventions could potentially generate shifts in attitudes towards progressive taxation and perceptions of fairness.
6. Conclusions
This study makes key methodological contributions to the belief system literature by employing advanced network models to analyze attitudes towards inequality. Mixed graphical models (mgm) effectively capture the unique associations between distributive attitudes, while the moderated network model (MNM) offers a powerful innovation for comparing belief systems across groups, overcoming the limitations of traditional split-sample approaches. The Ising model further proves its utility for analyzing binary data and simulating attitude change, enabling researchers to model systemic dynamics within belief systems. Together, these methods enrich the toolbox of belief system scholars, providing robust techniques for understanding how attitudes interact and evolve. Our simulations add further insights by demonstrating that targeting central nodes, such as the perception of large income inequality and the belief in public redistribution, produces downstream effects throughout the belief system. These findings confirm the theoretical premise that central attitudes drive broader adjustments, supporting Converse’s (Reference Converse2006) ideas on belief system dynamics.
This study demonstrates the value of the inequality belief system framework in analyzing the connections among diverse public attitudes towards inequality. By focusing on the role of anger, our work provides a novel contribution to understanding how emotions shape distributive perceptions, beliefs, and judgments. Although the link between anger and attitude strength is well-documented in broader research, this study is the first to examine its impact within inequality belief systems. Our findings reveal that anger moderates a significant portion of the network’s associations, intensifying both positive and negative connections, which consolidates the inequality belief system into a more polarized and contentious structure. These insights highlight the critical importance of incorporating emotional dynamics into the study of attitudes, deepening our understanding of how emotions drive public opinion on social justice issues.
The study has limitations which we hope will be addressed by future research. First, while our simulations provide valuable insights into attitude change within inequality belief systems, panel data are necessary to observe these dynamics directly over time and to avoid relying solely on simulated changes (Brandt & Morgan, Reference Brandt and Morgan2022). Additionally, the simulation of network dynamics followed an idealized model, borrowed from ferromagnetism. While the Ising model is valuable for formalizing belief system dynamics, it offers limited applicability to real-world intervention scenarios. This approach relies on a parsimonious set of parameters and does not account for the feasibility of changing targeted attitudes. Central nodes, while pivotal for triggering network-wide change, may also be the most resilient due to their high embeddedness. Future research could address these limitations by integrating well-developed experimental designs (e.g., Mijs & Hoy, Reference Mijs and Hoy2022) with network approaches, leveraging methods like network intervention analysis (Blanken et al., Reference Blanken, Van Der Zweerde, Van Straten, Van Someren, Borsboom and Lancee2019). Second, this study is not comparative, despite evidence that inequality belief systems vary significantly across societal contexts (Bertero et al., Reference Bertero, Franetovic and Mijs2024). A comparative approach was beyond our scope given the focus on modeling, estimating, and simulating belief systems, but future research could extend this work by exploring cross-contextual differences. Third, while we examined the role of anger—a key negative emotion—we lacked data on other emotional responses, such as positive emotions like satisfaction with public redistribution or other negative emotions like anxiety. Incorporating a broader range of emotional measures could further illuminate how feelings shape inequality belief systems.
Acknowledgements
The authors wish to thank scholars who participated in the ECPR Toulouse session “Network of Political Beliefs” for their important feedback on an early draft of the manuscript.
Funding statement
This research received no specific grant from any funding agency, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.
Data availability statement
This work is based on ISSP social inequality module data. Data are open access and available at the link: https://www.gesis.org/en/issp/data-and-documentation/social-inequality. The article’s analyses are based on the IPO protocol and are fully reproducible. Code is deposited on GitHub: https://github.com/arturobertero/consolidation_change_inequality_belief_systems.
Supplementary material
The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/nws.2025.10004.
Competing interests
None.