Hostname: page-component-669899f699-rg895 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-04-25T11:55:59.419Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Human capital-based growth with depopulation and class-size effects: theory and empirics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 March 2025

Alberto Bucci
Affiliation:
ICEA (International Centre for Economic Analysis), and University of Milan, Italy
Lorenzo Carbonari*
Affiliation:
Università degli Studi di Roma “Tor Vergata” and CEIS, Italy
Pedro Trivin
Affiliation:
University of Milan, Italy
Giovanni Trovato
Affiliation:
Università degli Studi di Roma “Tor Vergata”, Italy
*
Corresponding author: Lorenzo Carbonari; Email: lorenzo.carbonari@uniroma2.it

Abstract

Building on Lucas (1988) and Boucekkine et al. (2013), we develop a model in which the impact of population dynamics on per capita GDP and human capital depends on the balance of intertemporal altruism effects toward future generations and class-size effects on an individual’s education investment. We show that there is a critical level of the class-size effects that determines whether a decline in population growth will lead to a decrease or an increase in a country’s long-run growth rate of real per capita income. We take the model to OECD data, using a semi-parametric technique. This allows us to classify countries into groups based on their long-term growth trajectories, revealing patterns not captured by previous studies on the topic.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Aitkin, M. (1997) The calibration of p-values, posterior bayes factors and the aic from the posterior distribution of the likelihood. Statistics and Computing 7(4), 253261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altonji, J., Hayashi, F. and Kotlikoff, L. (1997) Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy 105(6), 11211166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angrist, J. and Lavy, V. (1999) Using maimonides’ rule to estimate the effect of class size on scholastic achievement. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(2), 533575.Google Scholar
Attanasio, O. P. and Weber, G. (1993) Consumption growth, the interest rate and aggregation. The Review of Economic Studies 60(3), 631649.Google Scholar
Bandiera, O., Larcinese, V. and Rasul, I. (2010) Heterogeneous class size effects: new evidence from a panel of university students. Economic Journal 120(549), 13651398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boikos, S., Bucci, A. and Sequeira, T. N. (2023) May human capital rescue the empty planet? Economics Letters 232, 111352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bosworth, R. (2014) Class size, class composition, and the distribution of student achievement. Education Economics 22(2), 141165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R., Martínez, B. and Ruiz-Tamarit, J. R. (2013) Growth vs. level effect of population change on economic development: An inspection into human-capital-related mechanisms. Journal of Mathematical Economics 49(4), 312334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boucekkine, R. and Ruiz-Tamarit, J. R. (2008) Special functions for the study of economic dynamics: the case of the lucas-uzawa model. Journal of Mathematical Economics 44(1), 3354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brambor, T., Clark, W. R. and Golder, M. (2006) Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analyses. Political analysis 14(1), 6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bricker, D. and Ibbitson, J. (2019) Empty planet: the shock of global population decline, Hachette UK.Google Scholar
Bucci, A. (2008) Population growth in a model of economic growth with human capital accumulation and horizontal r&d. Journal of Macroeconomics 30(3), 11241147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bucci, A. (2023) Can a negative population growth rate sustain a positive economic growth rate in the long run? Mathematical Social Sciences 122, 1728.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bucci, A., Carbonari, L. and Trovato, G. (2021) Variety, competition, and population in economic growth: theory and empirics. Macroeconomic Dynamics 25(5), 13031330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bucci, A. and Prettner, K. (2020) Endogenous education and the reversal in the relationship between fertility and economic growth. Journal of Population Economics 33(3), 10251068.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y. (2003) Consumption-based asset pricing. Handbook of the Economics of Finance 1, 803887.Google Scholar
Cervellati, M. and Sunde, U. (2013) Life expectancy, schooling, and lifetime labor supply: theory and evidence revisited. Econometrica 81(5), 20552086.Google Scholar
Cervellati, M. and Sunde, U. (2015) The effect of life expectancy on education and population dynamics. Empirical Economics 48(4), 14451478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalgaard, C.-J. and Kreiner, C. T. (2001) Is declining productivity inevitable? Journal of Economic Growth 6(3), 187203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feichtinger, G., Grassb, D., Kuhnb, M., Prettnerc, K. and Prskawetza, A. (2023) Resurrecting economic growth? Human capital accumulation as an antidote to depopulation.Google Scholar
Finn, J., Gerber, S. and Boyd-Zaharias, J. (2005) Small classes in the early grades, academic achievement and graduating from high school. Journal of Educational Psychology 97(2), 214223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fredriksson, P., Öckert, B. and Oosterbeek, H. (2013) Long-term effects of class size. Quarterly Journal of Economics 128(1), 249285.Google Scholar
Hazan, M. (2009) Longevity and lifetime labor supply: evidence and implications. Econometrica 77(6), 18291863.Google Scholar
Hazan, M. and Zoabi, H. (2006) Does longevity cause growth? A theoretical critique. Journal of Economic Growth 11(4), 363376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, J. and Singer, B. (1984) A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 52(2), 271320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. (1995) R & D-based models of economic growth. Journal of political Economy 103(4), 759784.Google Scholar
Jones, C. I. (2022) The end of economic growth? Unintended consequences of a declining population. American Economic Review 112(11), 34893527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kara, E., Tonin, M. and Vlassopoulos, M. (2021) Class size effects in higher education: differences across stem and non-stem fields. Economics of Education Review 82, 102104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konstantopoulos, S. and Chung, V. (2009) What are the long-term effects of small classes on the achievement gap? Evidence from the lasting benefits study. American Journal of Education 116(1), 125154.Google Scholar
Laird, N. (1978) Nonparametric maximum likelihood estimation of a mixing distribution. Journal of the American Statistical Association 73(364), 805811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laitner, J. and Ohlsson, H. (2001) Bequest motives: a comparison of Sweden and the United States. Journal of Public Economics 79(1), 205236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. E. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1), 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lutz, W. and Kc, S. (2011) Global human capital: integrating education and population. Science 333(6042), 587592.Google ScholarPubMed
McCullagh, P. and Nelder, J. A. (1989) Binary data, Generalized linear models, pp. 98148, Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLachlan, G. J. and Peel, D. (2000) Mixtures of factor analyzers. In: Proceedings of the seventeenth international conference on machine learning, pages 599606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2023) Education at a glance 2023.Google Scholar
Palivos, T., Wang, P. and Zhang, J. (1997) On the existence of balanced growth equilibrium. International Economic Review 38(1), 205224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siskova, M., Kuhn, M., Prettner, K. and Prskawetz, A. (2023) Does human capital compensate for population decline? The Journal of the Economics of Ageing 26, 100469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strulik, H. (2005) The role of human capital and population growth in R&D-based models of economic growth. Review of International Economics 13(1), 129145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strulik, H. (2022) Long-run economic growth despite population decline.Google Scholar
United Nations (2022) World Population Prospects, the 2022 Revision. New York, NY: Population Division, Department of Economic and Social Affairs.Google Scholar
Urquiola, M. (2006) Identifying class size effects in developing countries: evidence from rural Bolivia. Review of Economics and Statistics 88(1), 171177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vissing-Jørgensen, A. (2002) Limited asset market participation and the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. Journal of Political Economy 110(4), 825853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wößmann, L. and West, M. (2006) Class-size effects in school systems around the world: evidence from between-grade variation in TIMSS. European Economic Review 50(3), 695736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yogo, M. (2004) Estimating the elasticity of intertemporal substitution when instruments are weak. Review of Economics and Statistics 86(3), 797810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar