from Part II - The Combinatorial Clock Auction Designs
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 26 October 2017
Since its proposal in a 2006 academic paper, the combinatorial clock auction (CCA) has rapidly established itself as one of the leading formats for government auctions of telecommunications spectrum. Its initial implementations were for relatively small auctions and some of these applications may be viewed as experimental. However, in the past few years, usage of the CCA has gained substantial momentum. From 2012 to this writing in 2015, the CCA has been used for more than ten major spectrum auctions worldwide, allocating prime sub-1-GHz spectrum on three continents and raising approximately $20 billion in revenues (see Table 1). Despite the presence of an existing auction format—the simultaneous multiple round auction (SMRA)—which often performs reasonably well, the CCA has the potential of displacing it and becoming the new standard design choice for spectrum auctions.
The CCA design consists of a two-stage bidding process. The first stage, known as the clock rounds, is a multiple-round clock auction. In each round, the auctioneer announces prices for all items and bidders respond with quantities demanded at these prices. If aggregate demand exceeds available supply for any items, the auctioneer announces higher prices for these items in the next round. The bidding process continues until prices reach a level at which aggregate demand is less than or equal to supply for every item. The second stage, known as the supplementary round, is a sealed-bid auction process in which bidders can improve their bids made in the first stage and submit additional bids as desired for other combinations of items. Throughout the entire auction, all bids are treated as all-or-nothing package bids.
To determine winnings and associated payments, all bids placed during the clock rounds and all bids placed in the supplementary round are entered together into a standard winner determination problem (WDP). Winning packages are determined by finding an allocation that maximizes the total value (as reflected in bids) subject to feasibility constraints: each item can be sold only once and only one bid from each bidder can be selected as part of the winning allocation.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.