from Part III - Alternative Auction Designs
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 26 October 2017
Introduction and Background
The history of the continuous combinatorial auction marks the evolution of the mechanism. The concept of a combinatorial auction is due to Rassenti, Smith, and Bulfin (1982) who were motivated by the use of simultaneous ascending price auctions to allocate landing rights (Grether, Isaac, and Plott (1979 and subsequently published in 1989)). The ideas were generalized by Banks, Ledyard, and Porter (1989) to include the concept of a “standby queue” which serves a function similar to non-winning bids in the current system.
The first example of a continuous combinatorial auction is found at Brewer and Plott (1996). They demonstrate that representations in terms of binary confects of packages afford both the flexibility for widespread application and the computational speed required to support the auction. This early mechanism depended heavily on the existence of a fixed set of packages on which bids could be placed. The computer could quickly compute non-intersecting packages that maximized the value of the sale and permitted the auction to proceed as a type of continuous, simultaneous, ascending price auction. The packages played the role of items on which bids were placed. The nonintersecting packages that produced the most revenue from the auction were declared the leading bids at each instant of time. That first mechanism was followed by slight generalization to a procurement problem in which the buyer organized sellers to minimize procurement cost and sellers could offer endogenous packages. The organization was a simultaneous, decreasing price auction.
In the 1990s, the FCC was considering the adoption of a combinatorial auction as a replacement for the simultaneous, rounds-based, ascending price auction that the FCC had used to auction parts of the electromagnetic spectrum. The initial research focused on a hybrid process that consisted of rounds followed by a continuous phase. (See the report of Charles R. Plott, FCC Why River Conference, May 5–7, 2000). Experiments with the hybrid revealed that, that most of the adjustment and efficiently came from the continuous phase. That discovery led to the study of combinatorial auctions that operated only in continuous time.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.