from Part II - The Combinatorial Clock Auction Designs
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 26 October 2017
Introduction
Combinatorial auctions enhance our ability to efficiently allocate multiple resources in complex economic environments. They explicitly allow buyers and sellers of goods and services to bid on packages of items with related values or costs. For example, “I bid $10 to buy 1 unit of item A and 2 units of item B, but I won't pay anything unless I get everything.” They also allow buyers, sellers and the auctioneer to impose logical constraints that limit the feasible set of auction allocations. For example, “I bid $12 to buy 2 units of item C OR $15 to buy 3 units of item D, but I don't want both.” Finally, they can handle functional relationships amongst bids or allocations, such as budget constraints or aggregation limits that allow many bids to be connected together. For example, “I won't spend more than a total of $35 on all my bids” or “This auction will allocate no more than a total of 7 units of items F, G and H.”
There are several reasons to prefer to have the bidding message space expanded beyond the simple space used for traditional single commodity auctions. As Bykowsky et al. (2000) point out, when values have strong complementarities, there is a danger of ‘financial exposure’ that results in losses to bidders if combinatorial bidding is not allowed. For example, in the case of complementary items such as airport take-off and landing times, the ability to reduce uncertainty to the bidder by allowing him to precisely declare his object of value, a cycle of slots for an entire daily flight pattern, is obvious: one component slot not acquired ruins the value of the flight cycle. In the same situation substitution possibilities would also be important to consider: if flight cycle A is not won, cycle B may be an appropriate though less valuable substitute for the crew and equipment available. Allocation inefficiencies due to financial exposure in noncombinatorial auctions have been frequently demonstrated in experiments beginning with Rassenti et al. (1982) (see also Porter (1999), Banks et al. (1989), Ledyard et al. (2002) and Kwasnika et al. (1998)).
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.