Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-54dcc4c588-hp6zs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-10-03T22:52:45.794Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2025

Chenggang Xu
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California

Summary

This chapter, serving as the introduction, begins by posing a series of pivotal questions to engage the reader and by providing a summary of the key points. The section on institutional divergence paints a broad, motivating picture of the divergence in institutions since the late nineteenth century between Japan on the one side, and Russia and China on the other. Both Russia and China initially emulated Japan’s efforts toward a constitutional monarchy. After outlining the nature of China’s institutional evolution, the chapter then emphasizes how the concept of institutional genes, stemming from both China's imperial legacy and the institutional genes transplanted from Soviet Russia, can be utilized to explain the rise and development of communist totalitarianism in China.

Information

Type
Chapter
Information
Institutional Genes
Origins of China's Institutions and Totalitarianism
, pp. 1 - 58
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2025

1 Introduction

1.1 Overview

The fundamental institution of contemporary China is communist totalitarianism with Chinese characteristics. This institution differs fundamentally from non-communist totalitarian regimes, ancient Chinese systems. It also differs in many aspects from the Soviet Union. It originated in Soviet Russia and its deep roots in China are inseparable from the foundations of ancient Chinese institutions. How does this institution dictate the behavior of the contemporary Chinese government? How have China’s institutions and their basic features evolved to the shape that we observe today? In which direction will these institutions change in the future? Academic research in this area is generally weak and has many gaps. This book aims to strengthen academic research in this area and fill in those gaps. By doing so, I hope to establish a solid foundation for interpreting China’s historical and contemporary context, while offering insights that may assist in predicting potential future shifts. For those who care about China’s reforms, this provides the basis for recognizing where the country’s fundamental problems lie and for understanding how to reform its institutions.

In this book, totalitarianism refers to an extreme type of modern autocracy characterized by total control over society through a totalitarian party, which is categorically different from any political party (further explained in Chapter 8). A totalitarian party is a modern organization that applies modern methods of control and propaganda. The descriptive definition proposed by Friedrich and Brzezinski in Reference Friedrich and Brzezinski1956 is still a valid summary of the system. This definition identifies six fundamental, complementary components of the system: Ideology is at the core of the totalitarian party’s control of the populace; and the party monopolizes and relies on ideology, secret police, armed force, the media, and organizations (including businesses) throughout society and controls all resources through this channel (Friedrich and Brzezinski, Reference Friedrich and Brzezinski1956, p. 126).

The first totalitarian regime that fit the above definition emerged from the October Revolution in Russia in 1917. Since then, the world has seen totalitarian systems founded on various ideologies. However, the term “totalitarianism” was not coined until the 1920s. The value of a totalitarian ideology at the core of the system lies more in providing legitimacy, cohesion, and mobilization to the regime as a governing tool, rather than in its nominal expression, which has purposely been made misleading by the communists (see Chapters 8, 10, 11). In fact, its extreme autocratic nature determines that regardless of its nominal ideology, essential parts of its expressions will be grossly self-contradictory to the operation of that system. For example, for communist totalitarianism with a nominal ideology of Marxism, the fundamental ideology is the dictatorship of the proletariat and the party’s unquestionable ruling position (Leninism). These are not only the basic principles of the specific institutional arrangements of the totalitarian regime but also the basis of its legitimacy. However, the communist ideology of absolute egalitarianism and the Marxist ideology of human freedom with humanitarian connotations are in serious contradiction with the operation of the totalitarian system. Anyone who adheres to a given nominal ideology, yet disobeys the paramount leadership, will face severe punishment under the totalitarian system, regardless of their position. They may even face physical elimination, as was the case with figures like Bukharin and Trotsky of the Soviet Union and Liu Shaoqi and Zhao Ziyang of China, among others.

While the entry of communist totalitarianism into China was initiated and strongly supported by the Soviet Communist Party, it is indisputable that the establishment of a communist totalitarian system in China, at the cost of millions of lives, was a choice made by Chinese revolutionaries, not the Soviet Red Army. The question is, the end of the Chinese imperial system (dizhi 帝制)1 was brought about by a series of reforms and revolutions aimed at promoting constitutionalism,2 but why did China ultimately choose the opposite, totalitarianism? Moreover, a recent puzzle is why China is still stuck with totalitarianism after several decades of reform and opening-up and with private enterprise already dominating its economy.3 Why has the totalitarian system taken root in China so profoundly? A more fundamental and universal question is, why did human society give rise to a totalitarian system? Why did this system originate in Russia? What similarities exist between the institutional legacies of Russia and China? To answer these questions, this book proposes an analytical concept of institutional genes. “Institutional genes” in this book refer to those essential institutional components repeatedly present throughout history. In Chapter 2, we will discuss the definition and mechanisms of institutional genes in detail. Using this concept, we will analyze the emergence, evolution, and characteristics of contemporary China’s institutions from both a transnational and historical perspective. Additionally, we will explore the genesis of totalitarianism, particularly in Russia. The concept of institutional genes and its analytical framework are significantly inspired by institutional design (mechanism design) theory4 and the path-dependence theory of North in economics.

Between 1989 and 1992, totalitarian regimes in the Soviet Union and Central Eastern Europe collapsed. This series of historical events stimulated academic research on institutions and spurred significant developments in the field. Several scholars, such as North and Coase, received the Nobel Prize in Economics for their work related to institutions. Nonetheless, aside from Kornai’s work in 1992, most renowned political economy studies have not delved into the subject of totalitarianism, nor have they analyzed the transition from totalitarian to authoritarian regimes in those countries.5 This research gap in economics and political economics, in particular, has caused a lack of basic understanding of the regimes of China, the Soviet Union, and other former communist countries, making it difficult to anticipate or respond to political reversals in those countries. From an academic and policy perspective, this seems similar to the awkward situation economists faced in predicting and responding to the global financial crisis of 2008. However, the comprehensive consequences of a totalitarian superpower across the globe, from direct geopolitical, economic, and military impacts to the indirect influence on the institutions of other countries, far surpass the consequences of a financial crisis in terms of breadth and depth. The propositions discussed in this book, therefore, pertain to institutional evolution in general and are not limited to China, Russia, or countries experienced in totalitarian rule.

This book presents and develops the basic concept, or analytical framework, which I refer to as “institutional genes.” “Institutional genes” is a term I coined in this book. It refers to essential institutional elements that serve as the foundations for other institutional elements and often appear repeatedly in history. It is a methodological approach proposed for the in-depth analysis of major issues in institutional evolution. This book applies the institutional genes framework to organize historical evidence, using historical narratives to elucidate why the constitutional revolutions in Russia and China in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries faltered. It also examines the paradoxical outcome of these revolutions, which, rather than fostering constitutional principles, instead gave rise to totalitarian systems that contradicted them. Further, it sheds light on the crucial institutional changes that these two countries have undergone over the past century and their lasting influence not only on their own trajectories but also on the global political economy.

There are many conceptions of institutions. In this book, the discussion of institutions focuses on three fundamental elements: human rights, property rights, and political power. In connection with this focus, the Locke–Hayek thesis on the inseparability of human rights and property rights is reinterpreted in the context of the history and reality of totalitarianism (Chapters 2 and 3). The essence is that the property rights structure of any society is inseparable from the structure of political power in that society, as can be observed from the arguably most egalitarian distributional structure of Scandinavian regimes to the most unequal structures of communist regimes. Accordingly, the concept of property rights used in this book is based on the notion of ultimate control rights – a concept employed by Locke, Marx, Mises, Hayek, and Hart (residual rights, Hart, Reference Hart2017), and one that was widely accepted in academia and practice before the twentieth century. Chapter 3 explores the relationship and differences between this concept and the concept of a “bundle of rights” that has gained popularity since the twentieth century. Throughout the book, the origins of totalitarian systems are explored through historical narratives, emphasizing how the institutional genes of these regimes stemmed from a deep-rooted monopoly on property rights and power and the resulting social consensus that solidified these structures.

From the perspective of property rights and power structures, a totalitarian regime consolidates all property rights and power within society under the control of the totalitarian party, thereby subjecting all individuals’ human rights entirely to the party’s authority. In contrast, no dictator, government, party, or institution in any other autocratic system enjoys such comprehensive control over property rights and power. Furthermore, the nature of the totalitarian party dictates that it is not a political party in the conventional sense (as detailed in Chapter 8).

With the world currently facing the threat of the totalitarian power of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP), it is particularly important to revisit Mises’ warning at the end of the Second World War – that the free world’s multi-decades’ efforts to contain totalitarianism have all failed. Unfortunately, this warning has long been completely forgotten. The neglect of totalitarianism in academic and policy circles has allowed the CCP to receive unchallenged assistance from the West across various domains, fueling its meteoric rise not only in economic strength but also in the expansion of its propaganda, police, and military capabilities. Even today, recognizing the totalitarian nature of the CCP remains a significant challenge in the West. Under such favorable conditions, the collapse of the Former Soviet Union and Eastern European (FSU-EE) totalitarian bloc was followed by the unfortunate expansion of the Chinese totalitarian regime into a threatening superpower – a development that could not have occurred without the support of the United States and other democratic nations. Existing academic discussions on totalitarianism, while still valid, are largely based on decades-old literature. These discussions have often been confined to philosophy, intellectual history, or the historical records of Soviet Russia, with few efforts made to systematically study the comprehensive and fundamental mechanisms of totalitarianism within the context of the century-long rise of communist totalitarian regimes. Addressing these gaps, Chapters 6 to 8 of this book explore the origins of totalitarianism as both an ideology and a system, the reasons it emerged first in Russia, and the mechanisms through which it rises and operates.

Totalitarian regimes are characterized by the complete eradication of private property and total control over society through extreme violence. Such regimes emerged from a secular political-religious movement known as the World Proletarian Revolution. This movement, driven by the pursuit of egalitarianism and a form of secular messianism, relied on so-called class struggle, which was both highly seductive and inflammatory, fueled by hatred towards the so-called class enemies. However, this secular religious movement only succeeded in societies that possessed specific institutional genes – a highly monopolized structure of property and political power, along with a corresponding social consensus (Chapter 6). The communist totalitarian movement was first established in Russia because it had the necessary institutional genes to create such a regime. These genes included the autocratic Tsarist regime, the pervasive influence of Russian Orthodoxy, and the well-developed network of sophisticated secret (terrorist) political organizations (Chapter 7).

The Bolshevik Party, the world’s first communist totalitarian party, originated as a secretive political organization. Chapter 8 discusses the creation of this party and its transformation into a full-fledged totalitarian party, including the development of its operating mechanisms. The role and mechanisms of the institutional genes that facilitated the formation of the Leninist party in establishing and consolidating a totalitarian regime are analyzed. The creation of the Soviet regime involved the suppression of opposition through the dictatorship of the proletariat, the establishment of a Red Terror regime, the creation of comprehensive state ownership, and the formation of the Comintern (Communist International), the organization that spearheaded global communist totalitarian revolutions. The CCP and other communist parties around the world were established with the support of the Comintern, with their founding principles and operational mechanisms transplanted from the Communist Party of Soviet Union (CPSU). To this day, all the CCP’s fundamental principles remain derived from the CPSU. Additionally, Chapter 8 systematically analyzes the basic nature and operational mechanisms of totalitarian parties and how these evolved from the institutional genes of Tsarist Russia. This analysis is essential for understanding the nature of totalitarian parties in general, making this chapter crucial even for readers primarily concerned with China.

Chapters 4, 5, and 9 analyze the origins and evolution of the institutional genes of the Chinese imperial system and the mechanisms by which these genes impeded the development of constitutionalism within it. Chapters 1013 explore how communist totalitarianism was transplanted into China by the Comintern, how China’s institutional genes facilitated the establishment of this totalitarian system, and how a Soviet-style communist regime was formed. The chapters also delve into the evolution of communist totalitarianism with Chinese characteristics – regional administered totalitarianism – during the Great Leap Forward (GLF) and the Cultural Revolution (CR) in the Mao era, and how this system supported economic development and reforms during the post-Mao era, ultimately preserving CCP rule while leading China into the trap of totalitarianism. From these discussions, it becomes clear that the so-called “middle-income trap” phenomenon observed since the late 2010s is merely a manifestation of the totalitarian trap, inherent in the nature of totalitarianism itself.

The final chapter briefly discusses the institutional transformations of the FSU-EE totalitarian bloc and Taiwan through the lens of institutional genes and explores the implications of these transformations for China’s future. The key feature that distinguishes the Chinese system from the FSU-EE totalitarian regimes – Regional Administered Decentralized Totalitarianism (RADT) – was instrumental in enabling China’s private enterprises to flourish under communist rule during economic reforms, becoming the primary engine of China’s economic growth and thereby sustaining the Chinese Communist regime. However, the sweeping reversal since the late 2010s suggests that the CCP may not be able to fully escape the fate of the CPSU. The fundamental institutions of communist totalitarianism remain unreformable and economic reforms appear destined to fail (Chapters 13 and 14). Furthermore, the peaceful abandonment of totalitarianism by the FSU-EE communist parties was driven not only by economic stagnation but also by immense social pressure and a growing social consciousness regarding human rights and humanitarian values. These pressures and social consensus are deeply rooted in the institutional genes of the FSU-EE countries (Chapter 14). In comparison, China has a much weaker social awareness of human rights and humanitarianism. Additionally, under CCP rule, the military has long been involved in politics and the CCP has deliberately institutionalized the grooming of princelings as successors (Chapter 14). These factors suggest that even in the face of prolonged economic stagnation, it may be more difficult for the CCP leadership to peacefully renounce totalitarianism than it was for their FSU-EE counterparts.

The key to understanding Taiwan’s democratic transformation lies in recognizing the pre-existing differences in institutional genes between Taiwan and mainland China, as well as the fundamental differences between authoritarian Kuomintang (KMT) rule and totalitarian CCP rule in suppressing the institutional genes necessary for constitutional democracy (Chapter 14). First, the short-lived rule of the Chinese imperial system in Taiwan ended as early as the late nineteenth century, leaving only a shallow influence of Chinese imperial institutional genes on the island. During the Taisho democracy era under Japanese rule, Taiwan began to develop the institutional genes of constitutionalism, including local elections and the assembly of political parties. Furthermore, the Comintern never reached Taiwan and the KMT was not a totalitarian party. Under KMT authoritarian rule, the institutional genes of democratic constitutionalism were suppressed but not eradicated; in fact, some were able to survive and even grow, albeit with difficulty. During the authoritarian period, when the Republic of China (ROC) Constitution was partially implemented, these institutional genes saw significant development through local elections, the rapid expansion of private enterprises, and the spread of civil society. This led to a growing social movement towards constitutional democracy. Taiwan’s institutional transformation was achieved precisely because the KMT authoritarian rulers yielded to and responded to this tremendous social pressure.

1.2 Institutional Divergence

China, Russia, and Japan, at the turn of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, each endeavored to promote the establishment of constitutional government. Japan succeeded while China and Russia failed. Since then, there has been an ongoing institutional divergence between these three powers that has had a major impact on the world.6 Japan was the first non-Western country to establish a constitutional government and became the first developed nation outside of Europe and North America (a thorough discussion of Japanese institutional changes, including its period of militarism, is beyond the subject of this book). After decades of endeavors towards a constitutional monarchy and republic, which ended their imperial systems, Russia and China, respectively, created and transplanted totalitarian institutions that ran counter to constitutionalism.

Since the end of the nineteenth century, for the first time in 2,000 years of Chinese history, the reform advocates who tried to change the Chinese institution called the traditional Chinese institution the “imperial system” (dizhi). This tradition has continued to this day among Chinese intellectuals who are critical of the institutions of the Chinese Empire. This book continues this tradition. The closest term in political science to dizhi, the Chinese imperial system, is an absolute monarchy. However, the powers in the Chinese imperial system were much more concentrated, such that there was no boundary between sovereignty and property rights and no judicial institution separate from the executives (Chapters 3 and 4 will explain further). These make the Chinese imperial system categorially different from the absolute monarchy in Western Europe. The Tsarist imperial system is more similar to the Chinese system than it is to the Western European absolute monarchy (see Chapter 7).

The study of the Chinese imperial system is highly relevant to its economic position in the international arena. This book argues that the most important reason for China’s decline and the limitations imposed on its catching up is its great institutional divergence. A century and a half ago, China, or the “Great Qing Empire,” had the largest economy in the world. Its economy was bigger than the sum of the second and third largest economies at that time. However, since the mid nineteenth century, China had rapidly declined. Riots, revolutions, and civil and foreign wars persisted. Concurrently, two constitutional reforms faltered, leading to the collapse of the Qing Empire and the Republican Revolution. However, the Republican Revolution also soon faltered. As a result, China became one of the world’s poorest countries, mired in conflict.

In 1949, backed by the Soviet Union, the CCP established the People’s Republic of China (PRC). At this point, China’s per capita gross domestic product (GDP) was a mere twentieth of the United States’ (calculation based on Maddison [Reference Maddison2003]). The nation remained in severe poverty for the subsequent three decades under the new regime. It was not until the post-Mao reform that China experienced more than three decades of sustained rapid development and became the world’s second largest economy. In 2018, China’s nominal per capita GDP was nearly one-sixth that of the United States, or 30 percent of the US figure measured by purchasing power parity (IMF, 2019).

If China develops to follow a similar trajectory to those of Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan, its GDP per capita will reach half that of the United States within the next twenty to thirty years, by which time China’s total GDP will exceed that of the United States and the European Union (EU) combined. It would be the biggest challenge not only to the global economy but also to global science, technology, politics, and even the military, similar to the expectations or fears about the rapidly developing Soviet Union during the 1960s and 1970s, even though the per capita GDP in the USSR never exceeded one-third that of the United States (Maddison, Reference Maddison2003). However, China’s basic institutions differ significantly from those of Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan. So, will China’s development trajectory follow that of Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan, or that of the Former Soviet Union or even the Qing Empire? What will happen if China cannot even maintain stability? The answer hinges on China’s institutions and how they will change.

Why did China and Russia, despite initial strides towards constitutional governance mirroring Japan, eventually veer in the opposite direction? Why, after the infiltration of totalitarianism into China, did the painstaking efforts of China’s intellectuals towards constitutionalism partially dissipate and partially shift the momentum in favor of totalitarianism? Why did the imported totalitarianism find a deeper foothold in China compared to that in Russia, its birthplace? Addressing these questions is essential to understanding contemporary China’s institutions and to anticipating China’s future trajectories.

Initiated in 1868, the Meiji Restoration represented a significant departure in institutional evolution. It laid the foundation for constitutional governance in Japan. Despite the major twists and turns of militarism, the Meiji Restoration and the subsequent constitutional democratic reforms introduced during the Taisho period laid the foundation for the final establishment of a democratic system in Japan after the Second World War. Conversely, both Tsarist Russia and Imperial China, following their respective military defeats by Meiji Japan, embarked on a series of constitutional reforms and revolutions aimed at establishing constitutional monarchies and republics. These tumultuous changes led to the collapse of both empires. However, rather than establishing constitutional rule, they rebounded to form the world’s first and largest totalitarian regimes, respectively. And it was in China that the seeds of totalitarianism took the deepest root.

Russia’s defeat in the Russo-Japanese War of 1905 sparked a revolution that led to the establishment of a constitutional monarchy and the State Duma, the legislative body. Despite holding several sessions between 1905 and 1917 after general elections, the constitutional monarchy remained unstable, which paved the way for the Bolshevik Revolution. The Russian efforts towards constitutionalism started in 1814, at the end of the war against Napoleon. During that year, members of the Russian military elite found themselves galvanized by the example of the French Revolution and the desire for constitutional government in Russia was first kindled. This inspiration spurred decades of tireless work by the revolutionary pioneers, culminating in the establishment of a constitutional monarchy after the 1905 revolution and a republican provisional government in 1917. Although the century-long struggle for constitutionalism was fraught with turbulence and hardship, and the Provisional Government was weak and faltering, it was not exceptional compared to the tortuous journey towards constitutionalism in most countries around the world. What made Russia profoundly influential in human history was the Bolshevik coup of 1917 (interpreted as largely a collection of coincidences by many historians), which completely ended a century of efforts towards constitutional government in Russia and created the world’s first totalitarian system. Why did Russia have such difficulty achieving constitutionalism, yet later shift so easily to its opposite, totalitarianism?

By the time Soviet totalitarianism permeated China, the conditions there largely mirrored those of revolutionary Russia. Following its defeat in the Sino-Japanese War of 1895, China twice attempted to enact constitutional reforms akin to those in Japan, yet both attempts foundered. The drive for institutional reform was eventually transformed into a revolutionary call and, subsequently, the revolutionary objective pivoted from republicanism to its opposite direction, communism. After enduring several brutal setbacks, a new generation of Chinese revolutionaries embraced Bolshevik missionaries, the Comintern. They willingly adopted Soviet institutions and constructed a totalitarian system, which stood in stark contrast to the constitutional framework that their predecessors had originally aimed to establish. I refer to this significant shift as the “Great Institutional Divergence.”

Since its inception in Russia in 1917, totalitarianism has spread globally at an unprecedented rate, outpacing the expansion of any other ideology or institutional model in human history. By the 1970s, the world’s population under totalitarian regimes surpassed the combined membership of all Christian denominations, the world’s largest religion. Moreover, without exception, all countries that voluntarily embraced totalitarianism had been autocratic states with no prior experience of constitutional government. It is evident that this phenomenon cannot be solely attributed to the ascent of a single leader or the triumph of an armed insurrection.

However, research into the patterns in the emergence and evolution of totalitarian systems remains sparse. Many scholars specializing in institutional studies, including those focusing on authoritarian regimes, tend to disregard the distinct characteristics of totalitarian systems, such as those found in China and the Soviet Union, and their influence on other nations’ institutions that goes beyond geopolitics. Many China specialists tend to underestimate the Soviet Union’s foundational role in shaping contemporary China’s institutions. Additionally, numerous Soviet experts often overlook totalitarianism’s origins and its continuing impact on today’s Russia and the world.

1.3 China’s Institutional Evolution

The downfall of the imperial system in China heralded the advent of totalitarianism. A century ago, pioneers of constitutional reform and the Republican Revolution perceived constitutionalism as an inescapable route towards China’s advancement. Despite distinct approaches, both the Hundred Days’ Reform (戊戌变法) and the Xinhai (辛亥) Revolution shared the common goal of instituting constitutionalism and substituting China’s imperial institutions with successful models from developed countries. But these attempted institutional reforms and republican revolutions all failed.

The key question to be analyzed and discussed in this book is why China had difficulty establishing a constitutional system originating from the West (including learning from Japan) but ended up rapidly and firmly establishing a totalitarian system originating from the Soviet Union in a relatively short period. What were the institutional antecedents in China for such a development? Subsequently, China transformed Soviet totalitarianism into regionally administered totalitarianism (RADT), totalitarianism with Chinese characteristics, through the Great Leap Forward and the Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution.7 Having been deeply rooted in society, RADT formed the institutional foundation for China’s post-Mao reform and made the Chinese communist regime more adaptable and sustainable. What were the institutional origins of RADT? What is the relationship between RADT and the major challenges confronting China today?

There have been three dominant views on political reform in academic and policymaking circles about China’s more than forty years of reform. The first view holds that China’s national conditions or institutions are unique and that a democratic constitutional system is not suitable for China. The second holds that constitutional democracy is the ultimate objective of reform but a phase of neo-authoritarianism is needed as a transitional stage to develop the economy as a foundation for democracy.8 The third view rejects the above two perspectives and argues that China can, should, and indeed must implement reforms leading toward constitutional democracy.

China’s exceptionalism also often manifests in the form of the so-called “China model.” Does China’s uniqueness allow it to bypass the regularities universally observed by other nations? Can China’s economy sustain stable and continuous growth in the absence of constitutional democracy? These fundamental inquiries are what this book endeavors to tackle. Each of the three perspectives above relates to a series of basic social science questions: What are the main characteristics of China’s fundamental institutions? Why are these characteristics the way they are? How did they originate and evolve? Why did communist regimes emerge in Russia and China? Furthermore, what hurdles will China face as it transitions towards democracy?

Another prevalent view in academic and policy circles contends that economic development is an essential precursor to establishing constitutional democracy. This perspective argues that China requires a phase of neo-authoritarianism to address basic subsistence needs and foster a modern middle class before transitioning to constitutional democracy. However, as historical evidence abundantly demonstrates, in countries like Britain and the United States, the establishment of a constitutional democracy preceded an Industrial Revolution and economic development.

Philosopher Bertrand Russell concluded at the close of the Second World War that,

Ever since [Rousseau’s] time, those who considered themselves reformers have been divided into two groups, those who followed him and those who followed Locke. Sometimes they cooperated, and many individuals saw no incompatibility. But gradually the incompatibility has become increasingly evident. At the present time, Hitler is an outcome of Rousseau; Roosevelt and Churchill, of Locke.

(Russell [Reference Russell1946] 1957, p. 660)

John Locke was a trailblazer in modern constitutionalism and played a vital role in drafting the documents of England’s Glorious Revolution. His perspectives on human rights significantly influenced the US Constitution, the constitutions of all democracies, and the United Nation’s Universal Declaration of Human Rights. A century after Locke, French philosopher Jean-Jacques Rousseau proposed that individual rights should be limited, or even nullified, for societal benefit and the so-called “general will.” He also maintained that private property rights are a source of inequality. Rousseau’s theory was put into practice during the French Revolution’s Reign of Terror led by the Jacobins and inspired Gracchus Babeuf, who created the first communist movement with the aim of seizing power and wealth through violence to achieve absolute equality under the rule of a clandestine organization. The concepts and movements of Rousseau and Babeuf were further developed by Marx and Lenin, laying the foundation for totalitarianism.

Locke’s philosophy was never popular among Chinese and Russian intellectuals. Instead, thinking derived from Rousseau and Babeuf, and later developed by Marx and Lenin, prevailed among Russian intelligentsia and Chinese revolutionaries. To understand the origins of totalitarianism, a critical question arises: Why did Russian intelligentsia and Chinese revolutionaries embrace the ideas of Rousseau, Marx, and Lenin while rejecting Locke’s?

1.4 The Institutional Regime in Contemporary China: An Outline

The nature of contemporary China’s fundamental institution is a subject of ongoing debate. In this book, I characterize it as Regionally Administered Totalitarianism (RADT), as previously mentioned, a concept that I expound upon in Chapters 12 and 13, along with an analysis of the regime’s evolution. Essentially, it began with the total Sovietization of China in the early 1950s.

The foundation of the classic model of totalitarianism that China adopted from the Soviet Union was the Chinese Communist Party, formerly known as China’s “Bolshevik” party. This entity initially received substantial support from the Soviets. The CCP’s authority was absolute, with the party maintaining comprehensive control over the executive, legislative, and judicial branches of government, the armed forces, propaganda machinery and media, all resources, as well as all state and non-state organizations and enterprises. There was no separation between the party and the government. The party directly appointed all departmental officials and regional administration leaders at every level. Regional governments lacked autonomy, let alone sovereignty, and local party-state officials were appointed by their superiors within the CCP. In these aspects, China’s institutional regime mirrored the classic totalitarian model established in the Soviet Union.

In the RADT system, local party-state agencies are delegated with administrative and economic functions, as well as the bulk of resources, under the totalitarian premise of centralized appointment and political and ideological control. This institutional change from classic totalitarianism to RADT began in 1958 with the implementation of the Great Leap Forward and was solidified during the Cultural Revolution (1966–1976).

RADT was the institutional foundation of the post-Mao reform. In the initial three decades of reform, with the aim of preserving the regime, the party’s societal control passively slackened as private businesses flourished in downstream manufacturing and the service industry. Simultaneously, a limited degree of pluralism began to take shape. The emergence of private property ownership, community organizations, and limited ideological diversity, along with expansion of the media, gradually diluted the party’s dominance in socioeconomic matters and ideological discourse. This period witnessed a partial transition towards authoritarianism, more specifically, regionally decentralized authoritarianism (RDA),9 albeit this shift was transitory in nature. Since the second decade of the twenty-first century, despite many of China’s elites eagerly anticipating reforms towards constitutionalism, China’s system has instead reverted to totalitarianism, that is to say, RADT. It is important to note, however, that history’s so-called repetitions only recreate certain fundamental features in new circumstances, not every detail. Today’s return of RADT in China is no exception.

Constitutionalism as an ideology made its way into China decades before the establishment of the first communist totalitarian regime in Russia. When the Russian Bolsheviks created the CCP, most of its founding members had a very limited understanding of communist ideology (as detailed in Chapter 10). But why did communist totalitarianism gain a foothold in China instead of constitutionalism? Why did totalitarianism not maintain its classic form in China, as it did in other communist countries, but rather evolved into RADT? Why has RADT become so deeply entrenched and difficult to remove in China? The answers to these questions can be found by examining the characteristics of China’s institutional genes and the necessary institutional genes that underpin totalitarianism.

The institutions of Imperial China represent the most enduring and meticulously organized autocratic systems in global history. The long-term stable structure of the Chinese imperial system is directly related to its unique institutional genes. Some of the basic components of these institutional genes originated in the Warring States period before the establishment of the empire. During the early phase of the unified empire under the Qin and Han dynasties (from 221 bce to 220 ce), imperial institutions began taking shape. In the long process of the collapse of the imperial system and subsequent reunification, the institutional genes of China’s imperial system were significantly improved during the Sui, Tang, and Song dynasties (from 581 to 1279). In the following millennium, these improved institutional genes became highly stable. During the process of dynastic changes, they continuously replicated and evolved. After the Mongols and Manchus overthrew the Song and Ming dynasties, they abandoned their own ruling methods and adopted Han Chinese imperial institutions (see Chapters 4 and 5).

Institutional genes and the incentive-compatibility issue of the key players in institutional changes10 largely determined the fate of various reforms and revolutions in modern Chinese history. The half-century-long endeavor towards democracy and constitutionalism, from constitutional reform to the Republican Revolution, ended in failure. By contrast, the process of establishing totalitarianism in China was very rapid and firm. After the collapse of the Chinese Empire, some institutional genes from the imperial period continued to self-replicate in new forms within the totalitarian system until today (see Chapters 912). The crux of comprehension lies in recognizing the parallels between the institutional genes of China’s inherent imperial system and those of the imported totalitarian regime.

1.5 The Institutional Genes of Regionally Administered Totalitarianism

The governance structure under the RADT in contemporary China constitutes an institutional trinity: a tripartite blend of fundamental institutional elements that underpin China’s entire political and economic framework. Figure 1.1 delineates these institutional elements and their interconnections. The central box at the top represents the party-state bureaucracy, which lacks separation between executive and judicial functions. On the lower left, we see the party-state’s control over property rights and law, manifested in state ownership of all the land, a state-dominated financial sector, and a monopoly over the economy’s commanding heights. Lastly, on the lower right, we find the CCP’s control over official personnel and ideology. This power structure ensures the party’s absolute societal control, upholding stability by securing political, economic, and personnel support for the totalitarian system. Chapters 35 and 1012 delve deeper into what makes this structure qualify as an institutional gene of contemporary China’s regime and they trace its evolution.

Figure 1.1 The power structure of regionally administered totalitarianism (RADT).

In the RADT regime, local governments hold complete administrative and economic functions under the premise that all local party officials are appointed from above and that political and personnel matters are highly centralized. The absence of specific centralized directives or planning instructions to localities in terms of specific administrative and economic management is a fundamental difference between RADT and classical totalitarianism. Figure 1.2 encapsulates the salient attributes of the central–local governance framework and power distribution under RADT. To underscore the decentralization of administrative and economic authority, Figure 1.2 only illustrates the functional arrangement at the central and county governance levels. Although similar configurations exist at intermediate levels, they are omitted for brevity. As shown in Figure 1.2, grassroots local party-state authorities possess nearly all the fundamental functions akin to those of the central authorities. Additionally, local party-state authorities take the lead in overseeing the comprehensive management of these functions. The section will delve into the pivotal role the RADT system played in China’s economic reform. More importantly, Chapters 4, 5, and 912 will analyze the genesis, evolution, and continuity of this system throughout China’s imperial period as well as during the CCP’s revolutionary and governing periods.

Figure 1.2 Institutional genes of the regional governance structure under RADT.

China’s distinct RADT system came into being via the partial deconstruction of Soviet-style institutions during the Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution. Chapter 12 scrutinizes why, after the comprehensive transplantation of totalitarianism from the Soviet Union, China’s “continuous revolution” transformed into the RADT system.

1.5.1 Origins of the Institutional Genes of the RADT System

The institutions of contemporary China are inextricably linked to those of the former empire. To comprehend the genesis of the institutional genes underpinning China’s contemporary system (as depicted in Figures 1.1 and 1.2), we need to examine the institutional genes of China’s imperial system (Figures 1.3 and 1.4). A comparison of Figures 1.1 and 1.3 reveals striking resemblances between the institutional genes underpinning the power structures of both the imperial era and the present day. Subsequent chapters of this book will delve into the specific parallels between the institutional genes of ancient and modern China, the factors contributing to these similarities, and the mechanism facilitating their transmission.

Figure 1.3 The trinity of institutional genes comprising the governance structure of China’s imperial system.

Figure 1.4 Institutional genes of China’s junxian bureaucracy since the era of the Sui and Tang dynasties.

At the center part of imperial China’s trinity of institutional power, as depicted in Figure 1.3, was the bureaucratic system established under the Qin dynasty (221–206 bce), known as the junxian 郡县 (prefecture-county) system.11 The judiciary was always an intrinsic part of the bureaucracy. In this top-down bureaucracy, bureaucrats appointed by the emperor replaced the aristocrats’ rule over local areas during the Zhou dynasty. The judiciary was also inherently embedded within the bureaucracy. The primary threat to imperial authority was the potential rise of a new nobility from within the imperial system itself. Since the aristocracy that might arise within the imperial system was the greatest potential threat to challenge imperial power, the empire had to prevent that from happening whenever possible. The imperial land system,12 as shown in the lower left box in Figure 1.3, instituted since the Qin dynasty, served to eradicate the aristocracy.

However, the amalgamation of imperial land control and bureaucratic systems proved insufficient to prevent the emergence of a hereditary, de facto nobility, who often intended to be independent of the emperor. The imperial examination system, formally established during the Sui and Tang dynasties (with an earlier version introduced during the Han dynasty, though it was not fully institutionalized), as shown in the bottom right box of Figure 1.3, served as a critical personnel strategy that disrupted the intergenerational transmission of power among senior officials. It was an instrument of personnel control that safeguarded the emperor’s absolute authority over the bureaucracy. Simultaneously, it also served as a tool for ideological control, ensuring that all individuals entering the bureaucracy were properly indoctrinated with loyalty to the monarch. Upon the consolidation and refinement of this institutional trinity during the Song dynasty (960–1279), the emperor’s and the imperial court’s powers were effectively solidified. This robust institution of imperial rule remained unchallenged by any internally emerging powers for the subsequent millennium.

Establishing effective rule at the local level is a critical priority for any empire. Figure 1.4 illustrates the structure of local control within the Chinese imperial system, delineating the institutional genes of the junxian system. By juxtaposing Figures 1.2 and 1.4, the remarkable similarity between the junxian system and today’s RADT becomes readily apparent. Chapter 12 examines how China’s institutional genes have localized the foreign totalitarian institutional genes, which has led to the formation of China’s contemporary institutional genes.

Figure 1.4 depicts the core functions of the imperial court, which were divided among Six Ministries that were responsible respectively for personnel, finance, examinations and rites, the military, judiciary (mostly penal affairs), and public construction. Each was headed by a minister appointed by the imperial court. At the local level, the expansive empire was administrated by prefectural and county authorities, or by provincial, prefectural, and county authorities, each of whom was under officials directly appointed by the imperial court. Faced with the trade-off between ensuring absolute imperial rule and the effectiveness of that rule, along with the logistical limitations in terms of communication and transportation, the empire delegated all administrative functions to officials at varying levels of local governments while maintaining strict control over the officials themselves. Each level, from the imperial court to the county, housed offices for imperial personnel, finance, examinations and rites, the military, judiciary, and public construction. These offices mirrored the functions of the Six Ministries, with a magistrate overseeing these functions at the county level. The functional structures at intermediary levels followed the same pattern, although they are not depicted in the diagram.

The institutional genes depicted in Figures 1.1 to 1.4 evolved and were refined during 2,000 years of the empire, tenaciously self-replicating at the core of the imperial system. Whether it was a dynastic change due to a peasant uprising or a dynasty ruled by invading foreign powers, these institutional genes continued to be replicated. Even after the collapse of the imperial system, these institutional genes continued to dominate the path of China’s institutional evolution through the choices of reformers and revolutionary elites.

1.6 Institutional Genes: From the Imperial System to Communist Totalitarianism

Communist totalitarianism is not native to China; it is, in fact, an imported system. Those who oppose the adoption of constitutionalism and democracy in China assert that these are foreign institutions and thus they are unsuited for China, predicting their inevitable failure. However, totalitarianism is also foreign to China. Why, then, is it deemed “suitable for China”? Furthermore, why has totalitarianism rooted itself so deeply in Chinese society? These issues are addressed in Chapters 4, 5, and 912.

A prevailing explanation for the revolutions in twentieth-century China centers around the country’s profound nationalism. This explanation indeed captures some truth, as Chinese nationalism, whether overt or covert, played a pivotal role in the Republican Revolution and the May Fourth Movement, which laid the groundwork for the CCP. However, it is worth noting that Russia was the largest foreign occupier of Chinese territory by the end of the nineteenth century, a fact that was well known to the Chinese. Additionally, during the Russo-Japanese War, the Qing Empire supported Japan’s endeavors to expel Russian forces from China. If one applies the nationalism perspective literally, the Russian-inspired revolution should have faced strong opposition from nationalist revolutionaries during the post-May Fourth nationalist upsurge. Curiously, China’s radical revolutionaries, including prominent figures like Sun Yat-sen, Wang Jingwei, Liao Zhongkai, and influential participants in the May Fourth Movement like Chen Duxiu and Li Dazhao, avidly embraced the Russian Bolsheviks’ revolutionary ideas immediately upon being exposed to them. Why? Regardless of the strategic choices made by individual revolutionary leaders, the revolutionary fervor of the participating, fervently nationalistic masses was not only a factor that these figures could seldom generate on their own but also one that could not be overlooked. This book delves into this inquiry by examining the institutional genes of the traditional Chinese imperial system and the totalitarian system through the lens of incentive-compatible institutional evolution.

The Hundred Days’ Reform of 1898, which aimed at establishing a constitutional monarchy, was the first attempt in China’s 2,000-year history to challenge the imperial system. Liang Qichao, a leading advocate of this reform, once said there had only been rebellions, not revolutions in Chinese history. By revolution, he meant replacing autocracy with constitutional government; by rebellion, he meant a change of dynasty that kept the same institutions in place. Any institutional change that curtails royal authority is inevitably incompatible with the interests of those in power. Thus, such successful changes necessitate the involvement of external forces beyond the monarchy’s control. Royal authorities would never willingly endorse a peaceful transition to constitutional monarchy without significant external pressure, which is strong enough and has its own power base. However, two millennia of imperial rule in China eradicated the nobility and other significant independent sources of power, and the remaining sectors of influence outside direct royal control were kept minor and feeble.13 The institutional genes of the imperial system, with its highly monopolized control over land rights, predetermined that a constitutional monarchy would be an institutionally incompatible change.

Indeed, the Hundred Days’ Reform and subsequent Late Qing Reforms were merely expedient attempts at self-preservation by the imperial court. According to the principle of incentive-compatibility, once the threat to survival was removed, the imperial authorities would employ every resource at their disposal to resist restrictions and undermine constitutionalism. Consequently, the incentive-incompatible institutional reforms introduced to China during this period all failed in succession. Eventually, many of the reformers who had initially supported a constitutional monarchy regarded the imperial court’s reforms as merely in name only, and they turned to support the revolution aimed at overthrowing the empire. The Republican Revolution of 1911 ended the longest-lasting imperial system in human history, but it failed to establish a stable constitutional alternative. The most devastating force to destabilize the Republic was Sun Yat-sen himself, the leader of the Republican Revolution. He initiated a “Second Revolution” and personally dismantled the fragile constitutional system that had just been established. Chapter 9 will delve into the pivotal role the imperial institutional genes played in many ostensibly random historical events.

A series of failed constitutional reforms and the Republican Revolution paved the way for the emergence of totalitarianism in China. Shortly after the Bolsheviks established a totalitarian regime in Russia, they created an international arm, the Comintern, which established a branch in China, the CCP. This marked the historical beginning of totalitarianism in China. When the Comintern was seeking to promote global revolution, China was considered a peripheral target. But the Comintern’s efforts in all of their main target countries ultimately failed. Although the transition to constitutionalism is rarely seamless anywhere in the world, it is exceptionally uncommon for a country to willingly choose and successfully implement totalitarianism. What made China special that the CCP, with the support of the Comintern, developed so rapidly, eventually seized power, implemented the Soviet system, and further established totalitarianism with Chinese characteristics? The answer to this historical anomaly, explored in subsequent chapters, lies in the close relationship between the institutional genes of totalitarianism and those of the Chinese Empire. On the other hand, the institutional genes of the Chinese imperial system and those necessary for a constitutional system are not only far apart but also are in conflict with each other.

1.6.1 The Genesis of Totalitarianism in Soviet Russia

Russian Bolshevism was the world’s inaugural totalitarian system. Despite Marx’s assertion that a proletarian revolution could only emerge in the most developed capitalist economies, not in a backward place like Russia or China, the Bolsheviks claimed to be Marxist and labeled their revolution as proletarian. Why then was Russia the birthplace of totalitarianism? This question is directly related to an understanding of the emergence of totalitarianism in China and the future of China. The explanation in this book focuses on how the institutional genes of Tsarist Russia contributed to the creation of the Soviet totalitarian system.

Some authors describe the establishment of Soviet power by the Bolsheviks as a collection of coincidental events or the emergence of Soviet totalitarianism in Russia as the result of conspiracy, cunning, and brutal violence. Each narrative reflects important aspects of history. However, such large-scale implementation of violence requires many people to execute it voluntarily, even creatively and fanatically. The incitement, fanaticism, organization, and brutality of the Bolsheviks required a highly intense incentive mechanism.14 So, history cannot be accounted for purely because of a gang of conspirators’ atrocities. These same traits characterized the strain of Bolshevism that later arose in China with the support of the Comintern. The tragedies of China’s Land Reform movement, Campaign to Suppress Counterrevolutionaries, Anti-Rightist Campaign, and Great Leap Forward, followed by the Cultural Revolution, all demonstrate the enthusiastic and active involvement of millions of zealous followers, guided and motivated by totalitarian leaders. The revolution spearheaded by the CCP generated incentives potent enough to unite the entire nation, despite Sun Yat-sen’s description of the Chinese people as being as disjointed as “a sheet of loose sand.” So, what incited this unity? The emotional resonance and organizational discipline of the party cannot be solely ascribed to coincidence. If it was not purely accidental, what was the underlying mechanism?

Chapters 7 and 8 analyze the emergence of three institutional genes in the Tsarist period which led to the totalitarianism of the Soviet Union: the secret political terrorist organizations of late Tsarist Russia, the Eastern Orthodox Church, and the institutions of imperial rule under the tsars. From the outset, the Bolsheviks were markedly different from other Marxist parties in their organizational principles and methods, which were inherited from the secretive terrorist political organizations prevalent in Russian society. When Lenin founded the Bolshevik wing of the Russian Social Democratic Labor Party (RSDLP) in 1903, its foundational principles closely mirrored those of the Narodnaya Volya, or People’s Will, a prominent political terrorist organization of that era. Lenin’s brother, who was executed following a botched assassination attempt on the Tsar, was a local leader of the Narodnaya Volya and several of the early Bolshevik leaders had strong connections with the organization. Even leading figures of the international communist movement at that time, such as Karl Kautsky and Rosa Luxembourg, criticized Lenin’s Bolsheviks as a terrorist organization and asserted that the Soviet regime would bring a reign of terror.15

However, the totalitarian party vastly outstripped the secret political terrorist organizations in capability. The biggest difference lies in its systematic, highly appealing ideology, extremely strong incitement, and extensive, religious-like ability of mobilization that permeated society. The roots of this extraordinary mobilizing capacity can be traced back over a thousand years through the history of Christianity and the Church (see Chapter 6).

In his later years, Engels wrote about the origins of communism and socialism in early Christianity (Engels, Reference Engels1895). Kautsky also explored the origins of communist thought in the Bible, pinpointing the medieval Reformation as the genesis of the earliest communist movements. Characterized by extreme zealotry and brutality, these movements – some carried out on a significant scale – were a characteristic feature of the Reformation in certain regions of Europe (Kautsky, Reference Kautsky1897, pp. 12–17). They were evident in several towns and cities across Central and Western Europe, and sometimes in established short-lived communist societies, such as the Hussites in Bohemia and the Münster Commune in Germany. Many other aspects of Marxist thought, including the idea of historical inevitability, the downfall of the old world and the rise of a new one, belief in a savior and redemption, and martyrdom, have their roots deeply embedded in Christianity (see Chapter 6). In many ways, the international communist movement led by Marx and Engels resembled a second Reformation but with historical inevitability, communism, Marxism, and Das Kapital replacing God, Heaven, Jesus, and the Bible. Chapter 6, based on historical evidence from Europe, explains the Christian origins of a secular religion, that is to say, communist totalitarianism. It also explains how this institutional gene made communist totalitarianism the most influential ideology and institution at one point. This is the intellectual starting point for understanding fanatic communist movements in Russia and China.

Just as the Roman Empire’s greatest contribution to Christianity was its establishment as the state religion, the Bolsheviks’ primary contribution to the communist movement was the creation of a secular totalitarian caesaropapism founded on Marxist ideology. Regarding ideology and mobilization, the institutional genes for totalitarianism in Russia originated from the branch of Christianity dominant in Tsarist Russia: Russian Orthodoxy, which had permeated the population of the land long before the existence of the Russian Empire. Whether by design or inadvertently, the Bolsheviks appropriated the Orthodox Church’s well-established mechanisms of propaganda, organization, and punishment to mobilize, appeal to, and govern for centuries. Through these inherited characteristics of the Orthodox Church, the Bolsheviks infiltrated and exerted control over Russian society, from ideology to organization and power structures. While it may be coincidental that Stalin received a formal education at an Orthodox seminary, the Bolsheviks’ successful emulation of the Orthodox Church was more than mere happenstance. In this political religion,16 Marxism-Leninism’s classics supplanted the Bible, revolutionary martyrs displaced Christian martyrs, and communist society emerged as the new heaven. Mirroring the methods of the apostles in disseminating the news of Jesus Christ, the Bolsheviks established a cult of personality around their leader, elevating him to the status of a saint and savior. Revolutionary heroes and martyrs were canonized, their exploits commemorated, and temples erected in their honor. The religious custom of mass rituals was replicated, while penance to God was transformed into penance to the party. Liu Shaoqi coined the corresponding phrase “criticism and self-criticism” for use in China, a country devoid of a comparable religious tradition, in his 1939 book How to Be a Good Communist. Under Stalin’s regime in the Soviet Union, classic Marxist works served as the Old Testament, while Stalin’s History of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (Bolsheviks): Short Course (Stalin, Reference Stalin1975), supplemented by Lenin’s work on Bolshevism, constituted the New Testament. Mao Zedong adopted this blueprint, converting volumes of rehashed history into China’s uncontested “classics” and presenting himself as the “Great Savior of the Chinese People.”

Upon seizing power, the Bolsheviks soon dominated every facet of Russian society by controlling the government and all resources. The institutional genes for totalitarianism, in terms of practical control, originated from the Tsarist Empire. These include the Tsar and his court’s monopoly over political, economic, military, and judicial powers, the highly monopolized power structure of the system, control over the Church, and the social consensus (legitimacy) supporting the monopolization of power through violence. On this basis, the Bolsheviks developed a totalitarian system with a total monopoly of power and property rights that was unprecedented in human history, controlling all aspects of society wholly and comprehensively.

Marxist theory, echoing the Christian theme of salvation, posits that the international communist revolution can only triumph once everyone in the world achieves liberation.

1.6.2 The Rise of Communist Totalitarianism in China

The Comintern sent representatives to China soon after its creation but its delegates discovered that China was 500 years behind the advanced economies. According to Marxism-Leninism, such backwardness could only be peripheral to the Comintern’s operations. Yet, paradoxically, China emerged as the Comintern’s most significant success, if not its only success. As elucidated in Chapters 810, China’s institutional genes bore a striking resemblance to those that engendered Bolshevism, whereas they were distinctively different from those in the West. Of the three institutional genes that gave rise to Soviet totalitarianism, two similar ones were present in China: the imperial system and a tradition of secret societies. The monopolization of power, stringent controls, and the overall institutional stability of China’s imperial system were more pronounced than those of Tsarist Russia. Furthermore, China’s secret societies, such as the White Lotus Sect, the Green Gang, the Heaven and Earth Society, the Triads, and the Brotherhood Society, had a more extended history and were potentially more organizationally sophisticated than their Russian counterparts. This shared lineage of institutional genes facilitated the creation of a Bolshevik system in China and the launch of incentive-compatible communist totalitarian movements there.

However, one institutional gene that was crucial in the genesis of totalitarianism was absent in China: an Eastern Orthodox tradition. The emperors had curtailed the influx of Christianity and other Western ideologies into China. There was no widespread belief or consensus regarding a monotheistic God, God’s Truth, or a Savior, nor did any Church hold a national authoritative position. This absence limited the potential for generating totalitarian ideas in the vein of Marxism and Leninism and made it challenging to manifest such an ideology in the form of totalitarian institutions capable of penetrating and controlling society. Therefore, creating a totalitarian system in China necessitated direct involvement from an external force, such as the Comintern, to cultivate and support various aspects, including promoting beliefs, unifying thoughts, launching propaganda, and establishing organizations.

The largest insurrection in China’s late imperial period, the Taiping Rebellion, which spanned from 1850 to 1864, borrowed elements of Christianity. Certain Christian tenets were utilized to legitimize the uprising and proved highly effective in mobilizing the masses. However, Western missionaries and Western powers refused to support the Rebellion when they discerned that it was Christian only in name. In subsequent years, both Sun Yat-sen and Mao Zedong took Hong Xiuquan, the Rebellion’s leader, as a role model. Unlike the Taiping Rebellion, the Comintern directly introduced a new ideology into China, erected novel institutions, and actively endeavored to modify China’s institutional genes. As Mao Zedong declared, “The salvoes of the October Revolution brought us Marxism-Leninism.”

In 1920, the Comintern dispatched representatives to establish its branch in China. From the official establishment of the CCP in 1921 until the Comintern’s dissolution in 1943, the CCP functioned as a branch of the Comintern and identified itself as Bolshevik. All major decisions of the CCP had to be approved by the Comintern, which provided financial and material resources and selected the party’s top leaders. In 1931, under the Comintern’s guidance, the CCP founded the Chinese Soviet Republic, China’s first rudimentary totalitarian regime. From 1931, when Mao Zedong joined the CCP leadership, to 1938, when he ascended to the party’s highest-ranking leadership, he leaned heavily on the Comintern for recognition, direct support, and supervision. The party’s Yan’an Rectification Campaign in 1942 was a Stalinist purge with Chinese characteristics, after which Mao Zedong was elevated as the unchallenged leader who had full control over the CCP. From then on, the CCP became an independent Bolshevik party with a blend of institutional genes from both Imperial China and the Soviet Union, hence constituting a new and unique Chinese institutional gene.

After the Second World War, the CCP, with assistance from the Soviet Union, emerged victorious from the Chinese Civil War and subsequently established total control over China. From 1949 onwards, with the party serving as the linchpin of the regime, Soviet totalitarianism was comprehensively transplanted into China, encompassing diverse domains such as the economy, politics, law, military, education, and scientific research, among others. Even the inaugural constitution of the PRC was formulated under pressure from Stalin and with the assistance of Soviet experts; Stalin personally reviewed the final draft.

In places where totalitarian systems have developed, they often demonstrate significant strength in their early stages. Totalitarian parties employ methods such as incitement, violence, and coercion to generate extraordinarily potent incentives that result in the formation of the “masses.” These masses are manipulated into becoming formidable forces that dismantle the “old world” and construct a “new world” that paradoxically subjugates them in the end. Consequently, totalitarian parties seem to possess the capacity to establish systems that fundamentally contradict the incentives of the majority of individuals in society.

Unlike the establishment of totalitarian regimes, stable and long-term incentive-compatible systems that have emerged in human history have evolved slowly. This evolution is the process of synthesizing a large number of competitive, seemingly random short-term changes or events. In such an institutional evolutionary process, leaders and participants on all sides of the competition are mostly focused on short-term, local goals. For a conventional political party, including the early Social-Democratic parties within the communist movement, long-term objectives that were not incentive-compatible were unfeasible due to their lack of appeal for electoral support.

But a totalitarian party is an ideologically dominated, tightly controlled organization with iron discipline (internal factions are banned). The tight top-down organization and iron discipline of these parties enable them to promote highly seductive and inflammatory ideologies that conceal the truth and achieve their ultimate goal of eliminating competitors and gaining total control over society through a step-by-step plan. Ideology provides legitimacy for their totalitarian goals and step-by-step implementation is their strategy. Chapters 8 and 10–13 use historical evidence to analyze how the Bolsheviks and CCP decomposed their incentive-incompatible grand goals into multiple, often contradictory, short-term incentive-compatible goals, which were systematically and violently achieved through a divide-and-conquer approach.

Violence is an inherent component of totalitarianism. However, the resources available for violence are intimately tied to the totalitarian regime’s mobilization capacity. The violent upheaval of revolution, through which totalitarian systems are forged and refined, relies upon the mass mobilization of a substantial societal elite and working class, rallying them to the revolutionary cause.17 In China, the CCP effectively garnered mass support by leveraging China’s institutional genes to transform interim objectives into revolutionary acts or campaigns that aligned with the short-term incentives of a large populace. For example, it promised democratic freedoms to the elite and made commitments to secure land and property rights for the poor rural population. However, the CCP reneged on all of these promises, backed by coercive forces, within just a few years (see Chapter 11). Furthermore, these CCP actions were like a repetition to those of the Bolsheviks (see Chapter 8).

By strategically designing a mechanism for continuous revolution, inherently incentive-incompatible objectives can be decomposed into a series of short-term, seemingly incentive-compatible stages. This was the approach adopted by the Bolsheviks and the CCP extended this strategy to its extreme, with each stage of the revolution meticulously pre-planned. Ideology, proclaimed as “theory” by the party, provided a semblance of legitimacy for frequently self-contradictory initiatives such as the Land Reform movement and agricultural collectivization. In some instances, campaigns that served the established and long-term objectives were launched in response to specific events. One such instance was the Anti-Rightist Campaign, which was initiated in response to the “episodes” of the Hungarian Revolution of 1956 and Khrushchev’s secret speech to the 20th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU). Crucially, each short-term, incentive-compatible step in the process weakened or eradicated a segment of the political or social forces resisting revolution, including those within the party itself, thereby nudging the party closer to its incentive-incompatible totalitarian objectives.

The overwhelming majority of individuals, including many within the ranks of the CCP elite and leadership circles, would likely not have opted for totalitarianism had they been aware of its true characteristics in advance. With each stride towards complete totalitarianism, the system’s long-term incentive-incompatibility became more apparent to a greater number of people. The reason why a totalitarian system can still be established and solidified under such conditions is that the elimination of resistance and the establishment of totalitarian tyranny are advanced in a phased strategy. Every step along this trajectory involves the deployment of totalitarian organizations and collectives against individuals. At each stage, the party designs revolutions or movements that align with the short-term incentives to mobilize as many people as possible, aiming to gradually suppress or even eliminate dissenting individuals or groups in a piecemeal manner. At every juncture, the party harnesses sufficiently potent resources, reinforced by violence, to suppress or eradicate the targets of revolution specific to that stage. Individuals, recognizing their insignificance and helplessness in the face of this violent system, either surrender or even participate in the purging of others, thus becoming complicit in perpetuating the system. As this process repeats, the system amasses enough power to suppress any dissent towards the leader. Faced with a choice between obedience or purges under the threat of severe penalties, people generally opt for obedience, even if it entails participating in the purging of others. This forms the equilibrium of the totalitarian system under the tyrannical incentive-compatibility condition.

Although China’s imperial system was, arguably, the most centralized imperial system in human history, the modern totalitarian system is still far more centralized. In a totalitarian system, all means of production are owned by the state. The party, organized and controlled from the top down, uses ideology, personnel, and the armed forces as the basic means to take complete control of the government, the nation’s politics, economy, judiciary, ideology, armed forces, and every corner of society. In terms of the economy, along with thousands of Soviet experts and numerous Soviet-assisted development projects in the 1950s, the comprehensive operation of a Soviet-style totalitarian system also entered China. In this central planning system, the central ministries ruled the entire economy from the top down, a system that Mao described as a “vertically aligned dictatorship” (tiaotiao zhuanzheng 条条专政).

1.6.3 Institutional Genes: Regionally Administered Totalitarianism

While the personal role of Mao was important in transforming the totalitarian system in China from a classical one to one with Chinese characteristics, a much more important factor was China’s institutional genes. The most direct part of that was the local power pattern in the liberated areas before the CCP seized national power. And that in itself was a sort of extension of the institutional genes of the imperial junxian system. Before the CCP fully controlled China, the liberated areas were governed similarly to the imperial junxian system. Political and personnel matters were highly centralized, yet the regions maintained substantial self-rule in the administrative and economic spheres. The process of establishing a totalitarian system was a process of transforming China’s institutional genes with external totalitarian institutional genes. However, the “vertically aligned dictatorship” model of Soviet-style totalitarianism, introduced wholesale into China in 1950, proved to be significantly incentive-incompatible with the local power base of the CCP. Both the Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution, launched in 1958 and 1966, respectively, were attempts to discard this Soviet model and forge a totalitarian system that delegated more authority to regional administrations. Given that the transition towards RADT involved the reinvigoration of the imperial institutional genes inherited from the imperial era, there was a certain degree of truth to Mao’s self-proclamation in 1958 as a blend of Karl Marx and Qin Shi Huang, the first emperor of China.

The launch of the Great Leap Forward as a round of institutional changes first and foremost enhanced the paramount leader’s political powers, while simultaneously undermining or eliminating the already weak checks and balances that existed within the party and government. The powers of the central ministries were drastically curtailed and swathes of executive functions and resources were delegated to local governments. Newly empowered local governments were motivated to compete in loyalty to the leader, with regional competition supplanting central planning. Local governments were encouraged to experiment with new systems and strategies to expedite development towards communist totalitarianism (officially referred to as the transition to communism). Official propaganda declared that China should endeavor to be the first within the international communist movement to enter communism. The People’s Commune system was an invention of local governments during experimentation, while local competition was the mechanism for the rapid promotion of this system nationwide. In the process of dismantling Soviet-style totalitarianism and instituting RADT, however, the Great Leap Forward and the People’s Commune movement devastated the economy and sparked a famine on an unprecedented scale.

The Cultural Revolution, inaugurated in 1966 and spanning a decade, marked Mao’s second major attempt to advance the RADT system. Facilitated by a system that encouraged regional experimentation, the CR ignited a surge of Red Guards, Revolutionary Rebels, and Power-Seizing Movements nationwide. These forces, driven by personality cults and fueled by the mandate for perpetual revolution, wrought profound changes to China’s political landscape. Officials deemed inadequately loyal were brought down. All powers related to politics, personnel management, and ideology were concentrated in the hands of Mao and his associates. Central ministries and commissions were largely incapacitated and several were permanently dismantled. The administrative and economic responsibilities of the central government devolved almost completely to local authorities on a scale even surpassing that observed during the Great Leap Forward. By the early 1970s, China had morphed into an RADT economy characterized by multiple self-sustaining economies at various levels. The provinces and municipalities primarily functioned through self-sufficiency. The central party-state authority had to rely on local entities to implement its directives, thus transforming the so-called central planning into a task of coordination among local economies. Mao called this a “horizontally coordinated dictatorship” (kuaikuai zhuanzheng 块块专政).

In 1975, the principles and guidelines of RADT were officially incorporated into the constitution. Compared to classic totalitarianism, the primary shift this prompted was in the relationship between the central and local governments. The central–local governance structure inherent in the institutional genes of RADT is illustrated in Figure 1.2. As previously noted, in terms of the central–local relationship, RADT bears a striking resemblance to the institutional genes that governed the relationship between the imperial court and local jurisdictions under the traditional imperial system, as shown in Figure 1.4. While the disasters induced by the Great Leap Forward and the CR have been extensively studied, this book seeks to illuminate how these calamities established the groundwork for the transformations in China during the post-Mao era.

1.6.4 Changed and Unchanged Institutional Genes during the Post-Mao Reform

The chaos inflicted by the CR on the CCP party-state precipitated changes in the post-Mao era, during which the party shifted its focus from class struggle and proletarian revolution to economic growth. Following in the footsteps of the Eastern bloc, where economic reforms had been in progress for over a decade, the CCP embraced market socialism and perpetuated a groundless claim that Deng Xiaoping was the originator of market socialism.

Since the late 1960s, the Eastern bloc countries commenced a series of economic reforms to counteract their stagnating economies in order to maintain communist rule. In totalitarian regimes, however, economic resources are entirely under the control of the party-state and its bureaucratic machinery. Thus, the extent, form, and agents of change are inherently tied to the interests of the party-state bureaucrats. These bureaucrats may resist reform passively through uncoordinated collective inaction or they may even actively resist if reform threatens their vested interests. Thus, addressing their incentive problems is a prerequisite for the success of any reform and economic growth. If their incentive issues are not adequately resolved, the reform program will stagnate, regardless of the theoretical soundness of the proposed blueprint. Consequently, addressing the incentive issues for bureaucrats at all levels becomes one of the most crucial tasks in implementing reform. However, this presents a formidable challenge for any reform in a totalitarian state, including China.

The economic reforms in the FSU-EE were never able to overcome the fundamental political, ideological, and institutional shackles of totalitarianism, nor did they resolve the foundational incentive issues, leading to their failure. After more than two decades of attempted reform, the entire FSU-EE system collapsed between 1989 and 1992. In contrast, China embarked on its path of reform later than the FSU-EE countries but managed to make more significant progress in preserving the regime. The most crucial difference was that private enterprises grew from scratch to become an engine of the economy in China, driving rapid development during the reform. Along with the growth of the private sector, there was a short-lived shift from a totalitarian system to a somewhat relaxed authoritarian system. However, since 2012, the basic components of totalitarianism have been reinstated, making China’s successful reform temporary and preventing it from diverging from the trajectory of the Soviet and European reforms. Chapter 13 scrutinizes the evolved and unchanged parts of China’s institutional genes and their roles in driving the institutional evolution.

Two primary factors account for why China’s early reforms outpaced those in the FSU-EE countries. First, during the early stages of reform, China’s approach to interregional competition and experimentation, based on decentralized totalitarianism, was relatively effective in addressing incentive challenges across all levels of governance. There was a gradual shift towards the market replacing central planning, mirroring the direction of reforms in Eastern Europe. These alterations provided local officials with justification to tolerate, and even facilitate, the emergence and growth of private firms, even though technically they were not legal. Second, in order to reverse the devastating impact of the CR, the post-Mao period saw large-scale personnel changes throughout the party-state apparatus, with bureaucrats who favored economic development replacing those who favored class struggle. These sweeping changes at the top levels reduced resistance to reform and paved the way for progress across the board.

When the Cultural Revolution ended and reforms commenced, China was among the world’s poorest nations and the gap with rich nations was widening further which threatened the legitimacy of CCP rule. Under these extraordinary political and economic circumstances, the CCP pivoted towards economic development in lieu of class struggle. In the top-down regional tournaments of the RADT system, the competition target was shifted to the GDP growth rate. Motivated by the robust incentive of competition and encouraged to innovate to achieve higher growth, local governments tolerated and even fostered the private sector, facilitating substantial growth from the ground up of the private economy in many regions. A wave of private enterprises subsequently engulfed the nation, significantly reinforcing the reforms and propelling economic development. Private property rights were acknowledged and safeguarded under the constitution, while non-government organizations expanded alongside the burgeoning private sector. This evolution towards limited pluralism, encompassing the emergence of private enterprises, private property rights, non-government organizations, autonomous communities, and diverse beliefs nurtured the seeds of new institutional genes in China.18 In certain aspects, China’s governing institutions gradually transitioned from decentralized totalitarianism to decentralized authoritarianism.

RADT differs from classic totalitarianism at the operational level but fundamentally, they are both totalitarian systems. If, in the process of reform, the new institutional genes formed under the RADT (or RDA) system prove to be robust enough and if China’s communist totalitarian system undergoes sustained and gradual erosion as a result, then China might embark on a relatively smooth path of institutional transformation. However, the communist totalitarian system is not only highly alert to the risks of peaceful evolution but also deeply rooted in the RADT institutional genes. Due to the CCP’s strong resistance to fundamental totalitarian institutional reform, the “reform dividend” accrued in the early stages of reform quickly evaporated, barring China from becoming an anomaly among all communist totalitarian regimes. Ultimately, China will succumb to the same pattern that doomed institutional reform attempts in the FSU-EE countries.

The crucial reality is that even during periods when the CCP tolerated limited pluralism, it consciously preserved the fundamental elements of totalitarian rule. Deng Xiaoping, the paramount leader, underscored this in his Four Cardinal Principles, repeatedly stating that the CCP must remain China’s unchallenged ruling party and that the dictatorship of the proletariat must be maintained.

In practice, the party’s monopoly of and dependence on the secret police and armed forces have never weakened. The party consistently seeks to control every business and organization in the country, despite the fact that private enterprises have become the backbone of the Chinese economy. It maintains control over the media, even during brief periods of a loosened monopoly and fleeting spells of pluralism.

While the CCP has somewhat relaxed its grip on ideology, allowing for a degree of divergent thought as the intensity of ideology-related persecution has lessened, its domination in the ideological sphere remains unaltered. Additionally, it maintains control over all banks and the majority of the country’s financial resources. The complete state ownership of land not only remains unchanged but it has become even more crucial for the party-state’s local operations.

In the following chapters, we will delve deeper into the nature of the emerging institutional genes and their relationship with China’s pre-existing institutional genes. We will also examine the CCP’s monopoly of power and resources and its capacity to safeguard its own interests. By maintaining absolute control over society and relying on deeply ingrained totalitarian institutional genes, the CCP is capable of reverting to a totalitarian system, even after selectively loosening its control and encouraging a degree of limited pluralism.

In the early stages of reform, when China was not yet industrialized and still extremely impoverished, the reform was able to benefit the majority of the population. During this period, the incentive mechanism of local competition provided a strong motivation for bureaucrats, propelling economic growth and reforms closely tied to this growth, as long as these reforms did not threaten the totalitarian political-property structure. As a result of this reform, private enterprises began to emerge and grow throughout China, introducing nascent institutional genes related to private property rights, civil organizations, autonomous localities, and various beliefs.

China’s situation would have been quite different if the CCP had not insisted on maintaining its totalitarian rule, which, of course, would have been incentive-incompatible with the CCP’s interests. Under that scenario, during the window of opportunity when the regional competition mechanism was effective, if relevant institutional reforms had been promoted, if the rule of law had been developed in the direction an independent judiciary, if the community and grassroots self-governing organizations had been allowed to develop more freely, and if state assets had been significantly reduced, it might have been possible to fundamentally transform the role of government and allow new institutional genes to take root and flourish. Such changes could have potentially paved the way for the establishment of constitutionalism in China.

However, the CCP has been vigilant in preventing the “peaceful evolution” induced by private businesses. The period of emergence and development of new institutional genes was concentrated only in the late 1990s and early twenty-first century, when the Chinese economy was facing serious challenges. After joining the World Trade Organization (WTO) and experiencing relatively smooth economic development, the power of the old institutional genes quickly seized the opportunity to reorganize and grow significantly once again. The phenomenon of “the state advances, the private retreats” soon became overwhelming. The power of the old institutional genes overwhelmed the budding new institutional genes. As China became a middle-income country and conflicts over land resources between the government and the public intensified,19 the negative effects of the regional competition mechanism became more pronounced, causing the window of opportunity for using this mechanism to drive reform to be completely lost.

Just as China’s reform was facing a critical juncture, the global financial crisis struck. China’s institutional problems were overshadowed by the financial crisis. The government took this opportunity to implement a massive fiscal stimulus, highly dependent on the mechanism of regional competition, encouraging local governments to borrow heavily and to invest in infrastructure construction. This sparked an opportunist rush to develop high-speed rail and motorway and airport projects across the land, creating an economic “miracle” on the surface, while also sowing the seeds of deep problems, for example, the uncontrollable expansion of debt of local governments and state-owned enterprises (SOEs). The biggest problem is not the high debt itself but the expansion of a soft-budget constraint-producing institution that creates unstoppable borrowing. This institution is a common cause of the failures of economic reforms in all communist totalitarian countries.

With the underlying RADT institutions and the malfunctioning mechanism of regional competition, China’s politics and governance reverted to a vicious cycle of “chaos when loosened and death when tightened” that has been repeating itself for over half a century. The operating model for local government since the beginning of the reforms has been replaced by an increasingly centralized system during the Xi Jinping era. Local governments have lost their default limited power to manage administrative, social, and economic matters, including emergencies. The central authority issues orders and evaluates and monitors the performance of local governments. However, it was precisely this type of governance mechanism, along with other factors, that led to the quagmire of the FSU-EE countries. This mechanism was at the heart of the Soviet Union’s inability to solve various problems of reform, particularly those related to the economy and society.

From the outset, the ultimate aim of the CCP’s reform and opening-up has been to maintain, consolidate, and strengthen the party’s complete rule over Chinese society. The importance of economic growth lies in its ability to provide legitimacy for party rule; everything is done for the sake of party rule, which determines the primary character of the CCP’s post-Mao reform. The so-called beginning of the reform was at the same time the end of the CR, which had lasted for ten years. The devastation caused by the CR triggered a period of active political dissent more intense than any other in the history of the PRC, with participants ranging from ordinary members of the public to top CCP leaders such as Hu Yaobang. On the one hand, it provided an impetus for the cause of the reform but, on the other hand, it also challenged the totalitarian system in various aspects, including ideology and organization.

Deng Xiaoping’s Four Cardinal Principles represented the reaction to these challenges even before the reform started, the crux of which emphasized the paramount necessity of upholding the unassailable leadership of the CCP.20 To preserve the party’s dominance, Deng initiated purges within the party and stringent suppression of political dissidents. These movements included the campaigns against “spiritual pollution” and “bourgeois liberalization” in 1983 and 1985, respectively, and the brutal suppression of peaceful demonstrations in and around Tiananmen Square in 1989, leading to the imprisonment and house arrest of thousands of dissidents. Since then, all discussions of political reform have been stifled, rendering the topic forbidden. After Deng, the Four Cardinal Principles, underscoring the party’s supreme role in society, gained increased prominence, superseding even the law. At the CCP’s 17th National Congress in 2007, this political legacy was formally written into the CCP’s constitution. Xi Jinping has taken this still further. At the CCP’s 19th National Congress in 2017, Xi officially incorporated Mao Zedong’s Cultural Revolution-era principle of asserting party rule over everything under the sun (“The Party exercises overall leadership over all areas of endeavor in every part of the country”) into the party’s constitution. Reviving the core aspects of the old institutional genes in this way is a direct response to the challenges of the new institutional genes that emerged from China’s reform.

The most significant new institutional-gene components to emerge during the first three decades of the post-Mao reform were private enterprises, non-governmental entities, and limited ideological pluralism. The launch of the reform relied heavily on a comprehensive repudiation of the CR in the ideological realm. Some reformers, both within and outside of the party, conspicuously but quietly undermined the party’s absolute control over ideology and the absolute dominance of Marxism-Leninism-Mao Zedong Thought in the realm of ideas, which was previously enforced by violence. As reform progressed, social science subjects that had been officially criticized and only sporadically acknowledged within Chinese academia under labels such as “Western economics” and “Western political science” gradually became acceptable as they contain necessary knowledge for operating a market economy. University courses resumed, relevant literature was published, and the media reported on them systematically. An orderly limited pluralism of ideas emerged. But the cardinal principle or the fundamental restriction has never been relaxed: no one may challenge the dominance of the CCP and its ideology. No one may establish political parties or even political organizations.

As the purpose of the CCP’s post-Mao reform was to preserve and strengthen its rule, the economic development and reform had to serve this goal without undermining the party’s power. The massive erosion of the role of the state sector in the economy was an inevitable unintended consequence of the reform. Following in the footsteps of the Eastern European communist parties, the CCP began reforms after the end of the CR, focusing all attention on SOEs and issues related to incorporating the market into the planned economy. Rural land reform was driven wholly by local initiatives to resolve essential matters of survival in poverty-stricken rural areas. Under the constraints of prohibiting privatization, the SOE reform experienced a series of setbacks. By the late 1990s, the entire state sector was on the verge of crisis. The privatization of massive quantities of SOE assets at the end of the 1990s and the start of the twenty-first century catalyzed wholesale improvements in business efficiency throughout China. Yet, privatization was rebranded as “restructuring” to align with the communist ideology while concealing its essence as a shift in ownership.

At the peak of privatization, the CCP’s main focus was on strengthening large SOEs to preserve and reinforce party rule, a policy known as “grasping the large and letting go of the small.” The State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC) was established at that time with the same purpose in mind. The CCP leadership put forward the concept that “SOEs are the foundation of party rule,”21 in principle linking privatization with undermining party rule. Soon, even internal policy debate on privatization became a political taboo.22 The notion that SOEs were the foundation of party rule was enshrined in CCP regulations,23 setting political, economic, and ideological boundaries for the reform. In due course, the consequential role this played in reversing the trajectory of reform demonstrated the enduring depth and resilience of the institutional genes established in China during the 1950s.

The deeply entrenched existing institutional genes cannot be automatically supplanted by newly emergent institutional genes, nor will they allow new variants to erode the foundations of their power. The most integral component of these traditional institutional genes is the Leninist party which exerts control over all aspects of society. The foundation of any operational totalitarian system lies in the establishment, sustenance, and development of a party capable of permeating and governing the entirety of society. Without such a party, it is impossible to establish and maintain a totalitarian system.

From the inception of the Bolshevik Party, Lenin viewed the continuous recruitment of professional revolutionaries and the establishment of new branches as vital to the party’s survival. This type of work, referred to as “party construction” was later termed “party-building” within the lexicon of the CCP. This principle distinguishes Leninist parties from common political parties and was a primary cause for the schism between Lenin and the Second International. Since its establishment by the Comintern, party-building has been a fundamental principle for the CCP. After a century, it has become a firmly ingrained institutional gene of the regime in China. To most CCP members and cadres, the significance of party-building is so self-evident that the vast majority erroneously consider it a Chinese characteristic, often attributing its invention to Mao Zedong.

But this basic principle, the institutional gene of party-building, is in direct contradiction with the new institutional genes that emerged from the post-Mao reform. As private firms and non-government organizations flourished during the early twenty-first century, they accounted for the bulk of China’s urban employment. However, most of these companies and organizations did not have CCP cells. Meanwhile, the development of the real estate market has led to most urban residents living in private housing. These newly developed “neighborhoods” are basically devoid of party organizations. Although party branches are still nominally active in rural areas, the large-scale migration of rural residents to cities and village elections have greatly weakened the role of the township and village party branches.

As the twenty-first century began, CCP’s party-building significantly declined in terms of new member recruitment and the establishment of new branches. In the private sector, where most people worked, party branches were either missing or not actively functioning. For a period of time, the party lost its capacity to penetrate and manage every corner of Chinese society. This indicates that the nature of the Chinese system had for a time evolved from totalitarianism to authoritarianism, from RADT to RDA in particular, although unintentionally. If private enterprises were allowed to flourish, new institutional genes were permitted to grow and thrive, and old institutional genes were allowed to continue to decline, then not only might totalitarianism be completely eradicated but China could also progress from a more relaxed form of authoritarianism to constitutionalism and even a democratic system.

The declining trend in party-building has the potential to fundamentally undermine CCP rule and further weaken the old institutional genes. To preserve totalitarian institutional genes, it is necessary to reverse the trend of weakening control over society and the decline in party-building. In a bid to maintain control without hampering economic development, the CCP began experimenting with methods to transform private businesses and non-governmental organizations into entities under the party’s control. Utilizing a mix of party-building and direct authority, the party aimed to modify emergent institutional genes into versions more akin to the older institutional genes, in a manner more conducive to its interests.

To promote the buyout strategy on a large scale, the CCP amended its party constitution and the state constitution in 2002 and 2004, respectively. The amendments officially recognized private property rights and introduced the “Three Represents Theory.” This theory aimed to attract entrepreneurs to join the CCP and to select loyal entrepreneurs as representatives of the party and the People’s Congress. Entrepreneurs who aligned themselves with the party received significant benefits and protections, including access to financial and land resources, regulatory support, market access, and law enforcement. This made entrepreneurs dependent on CCP power and obedient to CCP commands.

If the CCP had successfully controlled the majority of private enterprises and non-governmental organizations, the developments of the reform period would not have led to the emergence of new institutional genes. However, buying out the entrepreneurs proved to be extremely costly and private firms proliferated throughout the country. As private enterprises became the mainstay of the national economy and non-governmental organizations increasingly dominated grassroots society, relying on a minority to buy out the majority became unsustainable and impractical.

New institutional genes were also emerging in other fields. Parallel to the development of private enterprises and NGOs, along with the development of limited ideological pluralism, the calls to promote constitutionalism and democratic institutions have been growing since the very beginning of the reform. In order to maintain total control over society, the CCP has never abandoned the use of violence and coercion to force entrepreneurs, NGOs, and political dissidents to comply. Political dissidents and non-compliant business owners have continued to be imprisoned throughout the entire reform period. Around 2006, debates about universal values (the basic values of democracy and constitutionalism) spread among intellectuals and the upper echelons of the CCP. There were activists who put their demands into action, drafting a constitutional charter and collecting signatures to promote constitutionalism. Viewing this action as a challenge to the old institutional genes, in 2009 the authorities imprisoned Liu Xiaobo for drafting and promoting Charter 08 and kept him in prison until his death (Link and Wu, Reference Link and Wu2023).

In response to the increasing call for constitutional reform in China, soon after Liu Xiaobo was awarded the Nobel Peace Prize in early 2010, the Chairman of the Standing Committee of the National People’s Congress (NPC), Wu Bangguo, declared on behalf of the CCP that the ideology of constitutionalism must be banned and the CCP must remain the leader of socialist China (Wu, Reference Wu2011). Furthermore, the party sought to constrain, and even eliminate, private ownership and ideological plurality. Such shifts indicated that China’s earlier reform phase, characterized by a move towards authoritarianism, had reached its limit, and that party leaders were now orchestrating a comprehensive return to totalitarian rule.

The evolution toward authoritarianism has come to an end. Xi Jinping, who took office at the end of 2012, became the prime mover behind the next dramatic shift. After taking office, Xi promptly traveled to Shenzhen to deliver a secret speech in which he attributed the collapse of the Soviet system to the lack of a “real man” who could have maintained the rule of the CPSU (Buckley, Reference Buckley2013). This stance overturned the CCP’s previous conclusion from the 1990s that attributed the collapse of the Eastern bloc to failed reforms. It also suggested that political suppression had become a more crucial tool than economic reform for the party to retain power. A few months after Xi’s address, the General Office of the party’s Central Committee issued an internal directive officially prohibiting debates on seven sensitive topics: universal values, press freedom, civil society, civil rights, the party’s historical missteps, the privileged bourgeoisie (quangui zichan jieji), and judicial independence.24 Journalists who disclosed the directive’s existence were jailed. In the spring of 2015, Wang Qishan, a member of the Politburo, clearly stated to Francis Fukuyama and Masahiko Aoki, who were then visiting China, that the party must control the judiciary and that judicial independence and rule of law were untenable in China (Tatsuhito Tokuchi, 2015).

Since 2013, Xi Jinping has launched a campaign to centralize power and suppress dissent in the name of anti-corruption. His approach has evoked memories of Mao Zedong’s Four Cleanups Movement (a prelude to the CR) and Stalin’s Great Purge. In association with the increasing political pressures created by this campaign, all private companies, foreign companies, and NGOs are required to establish party cells. Several attempts have been made to cultivate a Mao-style cult of personality around Xi but they have all been unsuccessful. The party has also demanded direct control over businesses, universities, and research institutes, regardless of their ownership.

It is evident that after decades of private business growth and China’s integration into the global economy, new institutional genes have not only emerged but also have become a fundamental part of Chinese society. People’s innate motivation to protect their own interests and the enlightenment gained from an open world have given vitality to these burgeoning new institutional genes. However, the existing institutional arrangements have ensured that the institutional genes of totalitarianism are never significantly weakened. As a result, the totalitarian party always has sufficient capacity to fully reassert itself. This is precisely what has happened in reality. Moreover, the party has been deploying cyber surveillance and artificial intelligence to control society to an unprecedented degree.

China’s future hinges on the interplay between the old and new types of institutional genes. Yet, under totalitarian rule, without potent exogenous shocks that could significantly weaken the totalitarian regime, it would be challenging for the new institutional genes to survive, let alone further develop. Conversely, even if the totalitarian regime were to collapse due to external forces, without sufficient development of new institutional genes supporting constitutional rule, China would still be unable to establish a constitutional democracy.

1.7 Two Additional Examples of Institutional Genes

The concept of institutional genes proposed in this book provides an approach to analyzing the mechanisms of institutional transformation. Fundamental institutional change is based on the evolution or mutation of a system’s underlying institutional genes. Without sufficient changes in these institutional genes, even well-intentioned actors’ forceful revolutions, reforms, or policies aimed at improving social welfare will fail if they are incompatible with the existing institutional genes.

Taiwan’s transformation into a constitutional democracy provides a good example of how institutional genes evolve and become the basis for a successful institutional transformation. Chapter 14 will use the evolution of Taiwan’s institutional genes as an example to discuss the successful transformation of democratic constitutionalism. Due to the Qing dynasty’s rule of Taiwan, some of Taiwan’s institutional genes were similar to those of China. However, during the Japanese colonial period, Taiwan’s institutional genes had already undergone some changes. After the Kuomintang took power following the Second World War, it implemented parts of the constitution of the ROC, local elections, and land reform. Taiwan gradually developed limited pluralism in property rights, ideology, and politics. This made the new institutional genes that had already emerged during the Japanese colonial period more solidified and they were able to expand. The emergence and growth of these new institutional genes laid the foundation for the institutional transformation in the late 1980s.

Conversely, Russia’s institutional transformation serves as a case in point that the direction and ultimate outcome of any institutional change fundamentally hinge on the degree to which the new institutional genes can counteract the existing societal institutional genes, irrespective of how impressive that institutional change might seem, how potent the political and ideological impetus is, or how much international support it receives.

During the late 1980s, the ideological stance of the top leaders of the Soviet Union, including Mikhail Gorbachev and Boris Yeltsin, was significantly more liberal and open compared to that of their counterparts in the CCP. Gorbachev’s Perestroika was a reform to liberalize and open up, a de-Stalinization reform, and a reform that fundamentally challenged the foundations of totalitarianism. In contrast, the reforms led by the CCP’s main reformists in China were designed to solidify and enhance the party’s control. Moreover, Perestroika built on and extended Khrushchev’s reforms of the 1950s. It was a policy choice made by the elites of the CPSU, informed by lessons from numerous failed reform attempts over several decades.

The Russian pro-democracy social elite, which included the liberal wings of the CPSU and intellectuals, had a much deeper understanding of the dark side of totalitarianism and the principles of constitutionalism than their Chinese counterparts. Their standing and political influence dismantled the totalitarian regime. However, without supporting institutional genes, constitutional rule could not be established. Due to the lack of necessary institutional genes required to establish a constitutional system, Russia ultimately descended into an authoritarian regime with some form of constitutional formalities.

The prevalence of private property rights and civil society are the most important missing pro-constitutionalism institutional genes in Russia. Without these institutional genes, it is impossible that a plurality of social forces can be formed from the bottom up. A sufficiently strong bottom-up formation of pluralistic social groups representing various social interests is the basis for guaranteeing checks and balances of power and is the foundation of constitutional government. Given that China’s totalitarian system came from Soviet Russia, and China and Russia share substantial parts of their institutional genes, the lesson of the Soviet failure to establish a constitutional government after the collapse of Soviet totalitarianism cannot be overlooked by anyone who cares about China’s future.

Figure 0

Figure 1.1 The power structure of regionally administered totalitarianism (RADT).

Figure 1

Figure 1.2 Institutional genes of the regional governance structure under RADT.

Figure 2

Figure 1.3 The trinity of institutional genes comprising the governance structure of China’s imperial system.

Figure 3

Figure 1.4 Institutional genes of China’s junxian bureaucracy since the era of the Sui and Tang dynasties.

Accessibility standard: Unknown

Accessibility compliance for the HTML of this book is currently unknown and may be updated in the future.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Introduction
  • Chenggang Xu, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Institutional Genes
  • Online publication: 03 June 2025
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108894708.002
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Introduction
  • Chenggang Xu, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Institutional Genes
  • Online publication: 03 June 2025
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108894708.002
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Introduction
  • Chenggang Xu, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Institutional Genes
  • Online publication: 03 June 2025
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108894708.002
Available formats
×